throbber
9/8/12
`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`
`TH
`
`OCTOBER  25,  2004
`
`ow  to  think  about  prescription  drugs.
`
`en  years  ago,  the  multinational  pharmaceutical
`company  AstraZeneca  launched  what  was
`known  inside  the  company  as  the  Shark  Fin  Project.
`The  team  for  the  project  was  composed  of  lawyers,
`marketers,  and  scientists,  and  its  focus  was  a
`prescription  drug  known  as  Prilosec,  a  heartburn
`medication  that,  in  one  five-­year  stretch  of  its
`extraordinary  history,  earned  AstraZeneca  twenty-­six
`billion  dollars.  The  patent  on  the  drug  was  due  to
`expire  in  April  of  2001.  The  name  Shark  Fin  was  a
`reference  to  what  Prilosec  sales—and  AstraZeneca’s
`profits—would  look  like  if  nothing  was  done  to  fend
`off  the  ensuing  low-­priced  generic  competition.
`The  Shark  Fin  team  drew  up  a  list  of  fifty  options.
`One  idea  was  to  devise  a  Prilosec  2.0—a  version  that
`worked  faster  or  longer,  or  was  more  effective.
`Another  idea  was  to  combine  it  with  a  different
`heartburn  remedy,  or  to  change  the  formulation,  so
`that  it  came  in  a  liquid  gel  or  in  an  extended-­release
`form.  In  the  end,  AstraZeneca  decided  on  a  subtle  piece  of  chemical  reëngineering.  Prilosec,
`like  many  drugs,  is  composed  of  two  “isomers”—a  left-­hand  and  a  right-­hand  version  of  the
`molecule.  In  some  cases,  removing  one  of  the  isomers  can  reduce  side  effects  or  make  a  drug
`work  a  little  bit  better,  and  in  all  cases  the  Patent  Office  recognizes  something  with  one  isomer
`as  a  separate  invention  from  something  with  two.  So  AstraZeneca  cut  Prilosec  in  half.
`AstraZeneca  then  had  to  prove  that  the  single-­isomer  version  of  the  drug  was  better  than
`regular  Prilosec.  It  chose  as  its  target  something  called  erosive  esophagitis,  a  condition  in  which
`stomach  acid  begins  to  bubble  up  and  harm  the  lining  of  the  esophagus.  In  one  study,  half  the
`
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`1/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 1
`
`

`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`9/8/12
`patients  took  Prilosec,  and  half  took  Son  of  Prilosec.  After  one  month,  the  two  drugs  were  dead
`even.  But  after  two  months,  to  the  delight  of  the  Shark  Fin  team,  the  single-­isomer  version
`edged  ahead—with  a  ninety-­per-­cent  healing  rate  versus  Prilosec’s  eighty-­seven  per  cent.  The
`new  drug  was  called  Nexium.  A  patent  was  filed,  the  F.D.A.  gave  its  blessing,  and,  in  March  of
`2001,  Nexium  hit  the  pharmacy  shelves  priced  at  a  hundred  and  twenty  dollars  for  a  month’s
`worth  of  pills.  To  keep  cheaper  generics  at  bay,  and  persuade  patients  and  doctors  to  think  of
`Nexium  as  state  of  the  art,  AstraZeneca  spent  half  a  billion  dollars  in  marketing  and  advertising
`in  the  year  following  the  launch.  It  is  now  one  of  the  half-­dozen  top-­selling  drugs  in  America.
`In  the  political  uproar  over  prescription-­drug  costs,  Nexium  has  become  a  symbol  of
`everything  that  is  wrong  with  the  pharmaceutical  industry.  The  big  drug  companies  justify  the
`high  prices  they  charge—and  the  extraordinary  profits  they  enjoy—by  arguing  that  the  search
`for  innovative,  life-­saving  medicines  is  risky  and  expensive.  But  Nexium  is  little  more  than  a
`repackaged  version  of  an  old  medicine.  And  the  hundred  and  twenty  dollars  a  month  that
`AstraZeneca  charges  isn’t  to  recoup  the  costs  of  risky  research  and  development;;  the  costs  were
`for  a  series  of  clinical  trials  that  told  us  nothing  we  needed  to  know,  and  a  half-­billion-­dollar
`marketing  campaign  selling  the  solution  to  a  problem  we’d  already  solved.  “The  Prilosec
`pattern,  repeated  across  the  pharmaceutical  industry,  goes  a  long  way  to  explain  why  the
`nation’s  prescription  drug  bill  is  rising  an  estimated  17  %  a  year  even  as  general  inflation  is
`quiescent,”  the  Wall  Street  Journal  concluded,  in  a  front-­page  article  that  first  revealed  the
`Shark  Fin  Project.
`In  “The  Truth  About  the  Drug  Companies:  How  They  Deceive  Us  and  What  to  Do  About  It”
`(Random  House;;  $24.95),  Marcia  Angell  offers  an  even  harsher  assessment.  Angell  used  to  be
`the  editor-­in-­chief  of  The  New  England  Journal  of  Medicine,  which  is  among  the  most  powerful
`positions  in  American  medicine,  and  in  her  view  drug  companies  are  troubled  and  corrupt.  She
`thinks  that  they  charge  too  much,  engage  in  deceptive  research,  produce  inferior  products,
`borrow  their  best  ideas  from  government-­funded  scientists,  and  buy  the  affections  of  physicians
`with  trips  and  gifts.  To  her,  the  story  of  Nexium  and  drugs  like  it  is  proof  that  the
`pharmaceutical  industry  is  “now  primarily  a  marketing  machine  to  sell  drugs  of  dubious
`benefit.”
`Of  course,  it  is  also  the  case  that  Nexium  is  a  prescription  drug:  every  person  who  takes
`Nexium  was  given  the  drug  with  the  approval  of  a  doctor—and  doctors  are  professionals  who
`ought  to  know  that  there  are  many  cheaper  ways  to  treat  heartburn.  If  the  patient  was  coming  in
`for  the  first  time,  the  doctor  could  have  prescribed  what’s  known  as  an  H2  antagonist,  such  as  a
`generic  version  of  Tagamet  (cimetidine),  which  works  perfectly  well  for  many  people  and  costs
`only  about  twenty-­eight  dollars  a  month.  If  the  patient  wasn’t  responding  to  Tagamet,  the
`doctor  could  have  put  him  on  the  cheaper,  generic  form  of  Prilosec,  omeprazole.
`
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`2/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 2
`
`

`
`9/8/12
`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`The  patient’s  insurance  company  could  easily  have  stepped  in  as  well.  It  could  have  picked
`up  the  tab  for  Nexium  only  if  the  patient  had  first  tried  generic  Tagamet.  Or  it  could  have
`discouraged  Nexium  use,  by  requiring  anyone  who  wanted  the  drug  to  pay  the  difference
`between  it  and  generic  omeprazole.  Both  the  physician  and  the  insurance  company,  meanwhile,
`could  have  sent  the  patient  to  any  drugstore  in  America,  where  he  or  she  would  have  found,
`next  to  the  Maalox  and  the  Pepcid,  a  package  of  over-­the-­counter  Prilosec.  O.T.C.  Prilosec  is
`identical  to  prescription  Prilosec  and  effectively  equivalent  to  prescription  Nexium,  and  it  costs
`only  twenty  dollars  a  month.
`Throughout  the  current  debate  over  prescription-­drug  costs—as  seniors  have  gone  on  drug-­
`buying  bus  trips  to  Canada,  as  state  Medicaid  programs  and  employers  have  become
`increasingly  angry  over  rising  health-­care  costs,  and  as  John  Kerry  has  made  reining  in  the
`pharmaceutical  industry  a  central  theme  of  his  Presidential  campaign—the  common  assumption
`has  been  that  the  rise  of  drugs  like  Nexium  is  entirely  the  fault  of  the  pharmaceutical  industry.
`Is  it?  If  doctors  routinely  prescribe  drugs  like  Nexium  and  insurers  routinely  pay  for  them,  after
`all,  there  is  surely  more  than  one  culprit  in  the  prescription-­drug  mess.
`
`T
`
`he  problem  with  the  way  we  think  about  prescription  drugs  begins  with  a  basic
`misunderstanding  about  drug  prices.  The  editorial  board  of  the  Times  has  pronounced  them
`much  too  high;;  Marcia  Angell  calls  them  “intolerable.”  The  perception  that  the  drug  industry  is
`profiteering  at  the  expense  of  the  American  consumer  has  given  pharmaceutical  firms  a
`reputation  on  a  par  with  that  of  cigarette  manufacturers.
`In  fact,  the  complaint  is  only  half  true.  The  “intolerable”  prices  that  Angell  writes  about  are
`confined  to  the  brand-­name  sector  of  the  American  drug  marketplace.  As  the  economists
`Patricia  Danzon  and  Michael  Furukawa  recently  pointed  out  in  the  journal  Health  Affairs,  drugs
`still  under  patent  protection  are  anywhere  from  twenty-­five  to  forty  per  cent  more  expensive  in
`the  United  States  than  in  places  like  England,  France,  and  Canada.  Generic  drugs  are  another
`story.  Because  there  are  so  many  companies  in  the  United  States  that  step  in  to  make  drugs  once
`their  patents  expire,  and  because  the  price  competition  among  those  firms  is  so  fierce,  generic
`drugs  here  are  among  the  cheapest  in  the  world.  And,  according  to  Danzon  and  Furukawa’s
`analysis,  when  prescription  drugs  are  converted  to  over-­the-­counter  status  no  other  country
`even  comes  close  to  having  prices  as  low  as  the  United  States.
`It  is  not  accurate  to  say,  then,  that  the  United  States  has  higher  prescription-­drug  prices  than
`other  countries.  It  is  accurate  to  say  only  that  the  United  States  has  a  different  pricing  system
`from  that  of  other  countries.  Americans  pay  more  for  drugs  when  they  first  come  out  and  less  as
`the  drugs  get  older,  while  the  rest  of  the  world  pays  less  in  the  beginning  and  more  later.  Whose
`pricing  system  is  cheaper?  It  depends.  If  you  are  taking  Mevacor  for  your  cholesterol,  the  20-­
`mg.  pill  is  two-­twenty-­five  in  America  and  less  than  two  dollars  if  you  buy  it  in  Canada.  But
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`3/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 3
`
`

`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`9/8/12
`generic  Mevacor  (lovastatin)  is  about  a  dollar  a  pill  in  Canada  and  as  low  as  sixty-­five  cents  a
`pill  in  the  United  States.  Of  course,  not  every  drug  comes  in  a  generic  version.  But  so  many
`important  drugs  have  gone  off-­patent  recently  that  the  rate  of  increase  in  drug  spending  in  the
`United  States  has  fallen  sharply  for  the  past  four  years.  And  so  many  other  drugs  are  going  to
`go  off-­patent  in  the  next  few  years—including  the  top-­selling  drug  in  this  country,  the  anti-­
`cholesterol  medication  Lipitor—that  many  Americans  who  now  pay  more  for  their  drugs  than
`their  counterparts  in  other  Western  countries  could  soon  be  paying  less.
`The  second  misconception  about  prices  has  to  do  with  their  importance  in  driving  up  over-­
`all  drug  costs.  In  one  three-­year  period  in  the  mid-­nineteen-­nineties,  for  example,  the  amount  of
`money  spent  in  the  United  States  on  asthma  medication  increased  by  almost  a  hundred  per  cent.
`But  none  of  that  was  due  to  an  increase  in  the  price  of  asthma  drugs.  It  was  largely  the  result  of
`an  increase  in  the  prevalence  of  usage—that  is,  in  the  number  of  people  who  were  given  a
`diagnosis  of  the  disease  and  who  then  bought  drugs  to  treat  it.  Part  of  that  hundred-­per-­cent
`increase  was  also  the  result  of  a  change  in  what’s  known  as  the  intensity  of  drug  use:  in  the  mid-­
`nineties,  doctors  were  becoming  far  more  aggressive  in  their  attempts  to  prevent  asthma  attacks,
`and  in  those  three  years  people  with  asthma  went  from  filling  about  nine  prescriptions  a  year  to
`filling  fourteen  prescriptions  a  year.  Last  year,  asthma  costs  jumped  again,  by  twenty-­six  per
`cent,  and  price  inflation  played  a  role.  But,  once  again,  the  big  factor  was  prevalence.  And  this
`time  around  there  was  also  a  change  in  what’s  called  the  therapeutic  mix;;  in  an  attempt  to  fight
`the  disease  more  effectively,  physicians  are  switching  many  of  their  patients  to  newer,  better,
`and  more  expensive  drugs,  like  Merck’s  Singulair.
`Asthma  is  not  an  isolated  case.  In  2003,  the  amount  that  Americans  spent  on  cholesterol-­
`lowering  drugs  rose  23.8  per  cent,  and  similar  increases  are  forecast  for  the  next  few  years.
`Why  the  increase?  Well,  the  baby  boomers  are  aging,  and  so  are  at  greater  risk  for  heart  attacks.
`The  incidence  of  obesity  is  increasing.  In  2002,  the  National  Institutes  of  Health  lowered  the
`thresholds  for  when  people  with  high  cholesterol  ought  to  start  taking  drugs  like  Lipitor  and
`Mevacor.  In  combination,  those  factors  are  having  an  enormous  impact  on  both  the  prevalence
`and  the  intensity  of  cholesterol  treatment.  All  told,  prescription-­drug  spending  in  the  United
`States  rose  9.1  per  cent  last  year.  Only  three  of  those  percentage  points  were  due  to  price
`increases,  however,  which  means  that  inflation  was  about  the  same  in  the  drug  sector  as  it  was
`in  the  over-­all  economy.  Angell’s  book  and  almost  every  other  account  of  the  prescription-­drug
`crisis  take  it  for  granted  that  cost  increases  are  evidence  of  how  we’ve  been  cheated  by  the
`industry.  In  fact,  drug  expenditures  are  rising  rapidly  in  the  United  States  not  so  much  because
`we’re  being  charged  more  for  prescription  drugs  but  because  more  people  are  taking  more
`medications  in  more  expensive  combinations.  It’s  not  price  that  matters;;  it’s  volume.
`
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`4/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 4
`
`

`
`9/8/12
`
`T
`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`
`his  is  a  critical  fact,  and  it  ought  to  fundamentally  change  the  way  we  think  about  the
`problem  of  drug  costs.  Last  year,  hospital  expenditures  rose  by  the  same  amount  as  drug
`expenditures—nine  per  cent.  Yet  almost  all  of  that  (eight  percentage  points)  was  due  to
`inflation.  That’s  something  to  be  upset  about:  when  it  comes  to  hospital  services,  we’re
`spending  more  and  getting  less.  When  it  comes  to  drugs,  though,  we’re  spending  more  and
`we’re  getting  more,  and  that  makes  the  question  of  how  we  ought  to  respond  to  rising  drug  costs
`a  little  more  ambiguous.
`Take  CareSource,  a  nonprofit  group  that  administers  Medicaid  for  close  to  four  hundred
`thousand  patients  in  Ohio  and  Michigan.  CareSource  runs  a  tightly  managed  pharmacy  program
`and  substitutes  generics  for  brand-­name  drugs  whenever  possible.  Nonetheless,  the  group’s
`pharmacy  managers  are  forecasting  at  least  ten-­per-­cent  increases  in  their  prescription-­drug
`spending  in  the  upcoming  year.  The  voters  of  Ohio  and  Michigan  can  hardly  be  happy  with  that
`news.  Then  again,  it’s  not  as  if  that  money  were  being  wasted.
`The  drug  that  CareSource  spends  more  money  on  than  any  other  is  Singulair,  Merck’s  new
`asthma  pill.  That’s  because  Medicaid  covers  a  lot  of  young,  lowerincome  families,  where
`asthma  is  epidemic  and  Singulair  is  a  highly  effective  drug.  Isn’t  the  point  of  having  a  Medicaid
`program  to  give  the  poor  and  the  ailing  a  chance  to  live  a  healthy  life?  This  year,  too,  the
`number  of  patients  covered  by  CareSource  who  are  either  blind  or  disabled  or  have  received  a
`diagnosis  of  aids  grew  from  fifteen  to  eighteen  per  cent.  The  treatment  of  aids  is  one  of  the
`pharmaceutical  industry’s  great  success  stories:  drugs  are  now  available  that  can  turn  what  was
`once  a  death  sentence  into  a  manageable  chronic  disease.  The  evidence  suggests,  furthermore,
`that  aggressively  treating  diseases  like  aids  and  asthma  saves  money  in  the  long  term  by
`preventing  far  more  expensive  hospital  visits.  But  there  is  no  way  to  treat  these  diseases  in  the
`short  term—and  make  sick  people  healthy—without  spending  more  on  drugs.
`The  economist  J.  D.  Klienke  points  out  that  if  all  physicians  followed  the  treatment
`guidelines  laid  down  by  the  National  Institutes  of  Health  the  number  of  Americans  being
`treated  for  hypertension  would  rise  from  twenty  million  to  forty-­three  million,  the  use  of  asthma
`medication  would  increase  somewhere  between  twofold  and  tenfold,  and  the  number  of
`Americans  on  one  of  the  so-­called  “statin”  class  of  cholesterol-­lowering  medications  would
`increase  by  at  least  a  factor  of  ten.  By  these  measures,  it  doesn’t  seem  that  we  are  spending  too
`much  on  prescription  drugs.  If  the  federal  government’s  own  medical  researchers  are  to  be
`believed,  we’re  spending  too  little.
`
`T
`
`he  fact  that  volume  matters  more  than  price  also  means  that  the  emphasis  of  the
`prescription-­drug  debate  is  all  wrong.  We’ve  been  focussed  on  the  drug  manufacturers.  But
`decisions  about  prevalence,  therapeutic  mix,  and  intensity  aren’t  made  by  the  producers  of
`drugs.  They’re  made  by  the  consumers  of  drugs.
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`5/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 5
`
`

`
`9/8/12
`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`This  is  why  increasing  numbers  of  employers  have  in  recent  years  made  use  of  what  are
`known  as  Pharmacy  Benefit  Managers,  or  P.B.M.s.  The  P.B.M.s  draw  up  drug  formularies—lists
`of  preferred  medications.  They  analyze  clinical-­trials  data  to  find  out  which  drugs  are  the  most
`cost-­effective.  In  a  category  in  which  there  are  many  equivalent  options,  they  bargain  with  drug
`firms,  offering  to  deliver  all  their  business  to  one  company  in  exchange  for  a  discount.  They
`build  incentives  into  prescription-­drug  plans  to  encourage  intelligent  patient  behavior.  If
`someone  wants  to  take  a  brand-­name  oral  contraceptive  and  there  is  a  generic  equivalent
`available,  for  example,  a  P.B.M.  might  require  her  to  pay  the  price  difference.  In  the  case  of
`something  like  heartburn,  the  P.B.M.  might  require  patients  to  follow  what’s  called  step  therapy
`—to  try  the  cheaper  H2  antagonists  first,  and  only  if  that  fails  to  move  to  a  proton-­pump
`inhibitor  like  omeprazole.  Employers  who  used  two  or  more  of  these  strategies  last  year  saw  a
`decrease  of  almost  five  per  cent  in  their  pharmacy  spending.
`There  is  no  mention  of  these  successes  in  “The  Truth  About  the  Drug  Companies.”  Though
`much  of  the  book  is  concerned  with  the  problem  of  such  costs,  P.B.M.s,  the  principal  tool  that
`private  health-­care  plans  use  to  control  rising  drug  costs,  are  dismissed  in  a  few  paragraphs.
`Angell’s  focus,  instead,  is  on  the  behavior  of  the  pharmaceutical  industry.  An  entire  chapter,  for
`instance,  centers  on  the  fact  that  the  majority  of  drugs  produced  by  the  pharmaceutical  industry
`are  either  minor  variations  or  duplicates  of  drugs  already  on  the  market.  Merck  pioneered  the
`statin  category  with  Mevacor.  Now  we  have  Pfizer’s  Lipitor,  Bristol-­Myers  Squibb’s  Pravachol,
`Novartis’s  Lescol,  AstraZeneca’s  Crestor,  and  Merck’s  second  entrant,  Zocor—all  of  which  do
`pretty  much  the  same  thing.  Angell  thinks  that  these  “me-­too”  drugs  are  a  waste  of  time  and
`money,  and  that  the  industry  should  devote  its  resources  to  the  development  of  truly  innovative
`drugs  instead.  In  one  sense,  she’s  right:  we  need  a  cure  for  Alzheimer’s  much  more  than  we
`need  a  fourth  or  fifth  statin.  Yet  me-­too  drugs  are  what  drive  prices  down.  The  presence  of  more
`than  one  drug  in  a  given  category  gives  P.B.M.s  their  leverage  when  it  comes  time  to  bargain
`with  pharmaceutical  companies.
`With  the  passage  of  the  Medicare  prescription-­drug-­insurance  legislation,  late  last  year,  the
`competition  created  by  me-­toos  has  become  even  more  important.  The  bill  gives  responsibility
`for  managing  the  drug  benefit  to  P.B.M.s.  In  each  therapeutic  category,  Medicare  will  set
`guidelines  for  how  many  and  what  kinds  of  drugs  the  P.B.M.s  will  have  to  include,  and  then  the
`P.B.M.s  will  negotiate  directly  with  drug  companies  for  lower  prices.  Some  analysts  predict  that,
`as  long  as  Medicare  is  smart  about  how  it  defines  the  terms  of  the  benefit,  the  discounts—
`particularly  in  crowded  therapeutic  categories  like  the  statins—could  be  considerable.  Angell
`appears  to  understand  none  of  this.  “Medicare  will  have  to  pay  whatever  drug  companies
`charge,”  she  writes,  bafflingly,  “and  it  will  have  to  cover  expensive  me-­too  drugs  as  well  as
`more  cost-­effective  ones.”
`
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`6/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 6
`
`

`
`9/8/12
`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`
`The  core  problem  in  bringing  drug  spending  under  control,  in  other  words,  is  persuading  the
`
`users  and  buyers  and  prescribers  of  drugs  to  behave  rationally,  and  the  reason  we’re  in  the
`mess  we’re  in  is  that,  so  far,  we  simply  haven’t  done  a  very  good  job  of  that.  “The  sensitivity  on
`the  part  of  employers  is  turned  up  pretty  high  on  this,”  Robert  Nease,  who  heads  applied
`decision  analysis  for  one  of  the  nation’s  largest  P.B.M.s,  the  St.  Louis-­based  Express  Scripts,
`says.  “This  is  not  an  issue  about  how  to  cut  costs  without  affecting  quality.  We  know  how  to  do
`that.  We  know  that  generics  work  as  well  as  brands.  We  know  that  there  are  proven  step
`therapies.  The  problem  is  that  we  haven’t  communicated  to  members  that  we  aren’t  cheating
`them.”
`Among  the  costliest  drug  categories,  for  instance,  is  the  new  class  of  antiinflammatory
`drugs  known  as  cox-­2  inhibitors.  The  leading  brand,  Celebrex,  has  been  heavily  advertised,  and
`many  patients  suffering  from  arthritis  or  similar  conditions  ask  for  Celebrex  when  they  see  their
`physician,  believing  that  a  cox-­2  inhibitor  is  a  superior  alternative  to  the  previous  generation  of
`nonsteroidal  anti-­inflammatories  (known  as  nsaids),  such  as  ibuprofen.  (The  second  leading  cox-­2
`inhibitor,  Merck’s  Vioxx,  has  just  been  taken  off  the  market  because  of  links  to  an  elevated  risk
`of  heart  attacks  and  strokes.)  The  clinical  evidence,  however,  suggests  that  the  cox-­2s  aren’t  any
`better  at  relieving  pain  than  the  nsaids.  It’s  just  that  in  a  very  select  group  of  patients  they  have  a
`lower  risk  of  side  effects  like  ulcers  or  bleeding.
`“There  are  patients  at  high  risk—people  who  have  or  have  had  an  ulcer  in  the  past,  who  are
`on  blood-­thinning  medication,  or  who  are  of  an  advanced  age,”  Nease  says.  “That  specific
`group  you  would  likely  start  immediately  on  a  cox-­2.”  Anyone  else,  he  says,  should  really  be
`started  on  a  generic  nsaid  first.  “The  savings  here  are  enormous,”  he  went  on.  “The  cox-­2s  are
`between  a  hundred  and  two  hundred  dollars  a  month,  and  the  generic  nsaids  are  pennies  a  day—
`and  these  are  drugs  that  people  take  day  in,  day  out,  for  years  and  years.”  But  that  kind  of
`change  can’t  be  implemented  unilaterally:  the  health  plan  and  the  employer  have  to  explain  to
`employees  that  in  their  case  a  brand-­new,  hundreddollar  drug  may  not  be  any  better  than  an  old,
`one-­dollar  drug.
`Similarly,  a  P.B.M.  might  choose  to  favor  one  of  the  six  available  statins  on  its  formulary—
`say,  AstraZeneca’s  Crestor—because  AstraZeneca  gave  it  the  biggest  discount.  But  that
`requires,  once  again,  a  conversation  between  the  health  plan  and  the  employee:  the  person  who
`has  happily  been  taking  Pfizer’s  anti-­cholesterol  drug  Lipitor  for  several  years  has  to  be
`convinced  that  Crestor  is  just  as  good,  and  the  plan  has  to  be  very  sure  that  Crestor  is  just  as
`good.
`The  same  debates  are  going  on  right  now  in  Washington,  as  the  Medicare  program  decides
`how  to  implement  the  new  drug  benefit.  In  practice,  the  P.B.M.s  will  be  required  to  carry  a
`choice  of  drugs  in  every  therapeutic  category.  But  how  do  you  define  a  therapeutic  category?
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`7/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 7
`
`

`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`9/8/12
`Are  drugs  like  Nexium  and  Prilosec  and  Prevacid—all  technically  known  as  proton-­pump
`inhibitors—in  one  category,  and  the  H2  antagonists  in  another?  Or  are  they  all  in  one  big
`category?  The  first  approach  maximizes  the  choices  available.  The  second  approach  maximizes
`the  bargaining  power  of  P.B.M.s.  Deciding  which  option  to  take  will  have  a  big  impact  on  how
`much  we  end  up  paying  for  prescription  drugs—and  it’s  a  decision  that  has  nothing  to  do  with
`the  drug  companies.  It’s  up  to  us;;  it  requires  physicians,  insurers,  patients,  and  government
`officials  to  reach  some  kind  of  consensus  about  what  we  want  from  our  medical  system,  and
`how  much  we  are  willing  to  pay  for  it.  AstraZeneca  was  able  to  do  some  chemical  sleight  of
`hand,  spend  half  a  billion  on  advertising,  and  get  away  with  the  “reinvention”  of  its  heartburn
`drug  only  because  that  consensus  hasn’t  yet  been  reached.  For  sellers  to  behave  responsibly,
`buyers  must  first  behave  intelligently.  And  if  we  want  to  create  a  system  where  millions  of
`working  and  elderly  Americans  don’t  have  to  struggle  to  pay  for  prescription  drugs  that’s  also
`up  to  us.  We  could  find  it  in  our  hearts  to  provide  all  Americans  with  adequate  health  insurance.
`It  is  only  by  the  most  spectacular  feat  of  cynicism  that  our  political  system’s  moral  negligence
`has  become  the  fault  of  the  pharmaceutical  industry.
`There  is  a  second  book  out  this  fall  on  the  prescription-­drug  crisis,  called  “Overdosed
`America”  (HarperCollins;;  $24.95),  by  John  Abramson,  who  teaches  at  Harvard  Medical  School.
`At  one  point,  Abramson  discusses  a  study  that  he  found  in  a  medical  journal  concluding  that  the
`statin  Pravachol  lowered  the  risk  of  stroke  in  patients  with  coronary  heart  disease  by  nineteen
`per  cent.  That  sounds  like  a  significant  finding,  but,  as  Abramson  shows,  it  isn’t.  In  the  six  years
`of  the  study,  4.5  per  cent  of  those  taking  a  placebo  had  a  stroke  versus  3.7  per  cent  of  those  on
`Pravachol.  In  the  real  world,  that  means  that  for  every  thousand  people  you  put  on  Pravachol
`you  prevent  one  stroke—which,  given  how  much  the  drug  costs,  comes  to  at  least  $1.2  million
`per  stroke  prevented.  On  top  of  that,  the  study’s  participants  had  an  average  age  of  sixty-­two
`and  most  of  them  were  men.  Stroke  victims,  however,  are  more  likely  to  be  female,  and,  on
`average,  much  older—and  the  patients  older  than  seventy  in  the  study  who  were  taking
`Pravachol  had  more  strokes  than  those  who  were  on  a  placebo.
`Here  is  a  classic  case  of  the  kind  of  thing  that  bedevils  the  American  health  system—
`dubious  findings  that,  without  careful  evaluation,  have  the  potential  to  drive  up  costs.  But
`whose  fault  is  it?  It’s  hard  to  blame  Pravachol’s  manufacturer,  Bristol-­Myers  Squibb.  The
`study’s  principal  objective  was  to  look  at  Pravachol’s  effectiveness  in  fighting  heart  attacks;;
`the  company  was  simply  using  that  patient  population  to  make  a  secondary  observation  about
`strokes.  In  any  case,  Bristol-­Myers  didn’t  write  up  the  results.  A  group  of  cardiologists  from
`New  Zealand  and  Australia  did,  and  they  hardly  tried  to  hide  Pravachol’s  shortcomings  in
`women  and  older  people.  All  those  data  are  presented  in  a  large  chart  on  the  study’s  third  page.
`What’s  wrong  is  the  context  in  which  the  study’s  findings  are  presented.  The  abstract  at  the
`
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`8/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 8
`
`

`
`High Prices : The New Yorker
`9/8/12
`beginning  ought  to  have  been  rewritten.  The  conclusion  needs  a  much  clearer  explanation  of
`how  the  findings  add  to  our  understanding  of  stroke  prevention.  There  is  no  accompanying
`commentary  that  points  out  the  extreme  cost-­ineffectiveness  of  Pravachol  as  a  stroke
`medication—and  all  those  are  faults  of  the  medical  journal’s  editorial  staff.  In  the  end,  the  fight
`to  keep  drug  spending  under  control  is  principally  a  matter  of  information,  of  proper
`communication  among  everyone  who  prescribes  and  pays  for  and  ultimately  uses  drugs  about
`what  works  and  what  doesn’t,  and  what  makes  economic  sense  and  what  doesn’t—and  medical
`journals  play  a  critical  role  in  this  process.  As  Abramson  writes:
`
`When  I  finished  analyzing  the  article  and  understood  that  the  title  didn’t  tell  the  whole  story,  that  the  findings  were  not  statistically
`significant,  and  that  Pravachol  appeared  to  cause  more  strokes  in  the  population  at  greater  risk,  it  felt  like  a  violation  of  the  trust  that  doctors
`(including  me)  place  in  the  research  published  in  respected  medical  journals.  
`
`The  journal  in  which  the  Pravachol  article  appeared,  incidentally,  was  The  New  England
`Journal  of  Medicine.  And  its  editor  at  the  time  the  paper  was  accepted  for  publication?  Dr.
`Marcia  Angell.  Physician,  heal  thyself.  ♦
`Subscribe  now  to  get  more  of  The  New  Yorker's  signature  mix  of  politics,  culture,  and  the  arts.
`
`www.newyorker.com/archive/2004/10/25/041025crat_atlarge?printable=true
`
`9/9
`
`MYLAN PHARMS. INC. EXHIBIT 1131 PAGE 9

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket