throbber

`
`
`
`33
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 2
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 1
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 1
`
`

`

`
`
`_
`
`o
`H.
`istorlca
`
`1 P
`
`o
`.
`erspectives
`
`J
`
`AS YET no general study of auctioning on a historical basis
`
`3 has appeared. The miscellaneous material available, how-
`
`ever, suggests that auctions have had a long and colorful
`history.
`
`Auctioning in Ancient Times
`According to Herodotus, auctions existed around 500
`B.C. in Babylon, where once a year women of marriage—
`able age were sold on condition that they be wed.1 When
`beautiful maidens were oflered, bidding among well—to—
`do swains was lively; but when less attractive girls were
`put up for sale, those seeking wives accepted them only
`in return for monetary compensation. In a kind of inverse
`auction, the plainer lasses went to impecunious, or per—
`haps miserly, persons who agreed to marry them in ex—
`change for money (see fig. 2). Payment took the form
`of dowries, presumably derived from the premium prices
`obtained for the handsome maidens, and the rivals made
`successive reductions in bids until they reached the mini—
`mum amount they would be willing to accept in return
`for the acquisition of less comely mates.
`
`I Herodotus, The Historic: of Herodotur, trans. Henry Cary
`(New York: D. Appleton and Company, 1899), p. 77.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`AUCV
`
`Alli)?
`
`BALE
`
`A1
`
`oldei
`fI'OIT
`In 01
`
`pee};
`of e
`
`frog
`bool
`1V
`
`a C6
`
`__ ii:
`1101:
`
`,7:
`:
`
`?
`
`Sys:
`Ru
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 3
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 2
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 2
`
`

`

`
`
`Desirability of chattel
`
`Absence of desirability of chattel
`
`Prices-
`
`orful
`
`d 500
`riage—
`Nhen
`ell—to—
`were
`
`. only
`1verse
`
`r per—
`in ex—
`form
`
`prices
`made
`mini—
`return
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`y Cary
`Fig. 2 Orthodox and reverse procedures in Babylonian wife auctions.
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 4
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 3
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 3
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`,.,___nm/
`
`
`
`
`
` old
`
`. frt
`
`--ml?»-
`
`28
`
`Auction: and Auctioneering
`
`Auctions were also used by the ancient Romans in commercial
`trade, at least to some extent. They were held in what was called an
`atrium auctionarium, where samples of the goods were probably dis—
`played prior to the sale. Trading activity was usually carried on by
`four functionaries: the dominur, on whose behalf the property was
`sold; the argentarius, who organized, regulated, and possibly even
`financed the auction sale; the praeeo, who advertised and promoted
`the auction and conducted the bidding; and the emptor, who, as
`the highest bidder, purchased the goods?
`Few details are available concerning the modm operandi of
`these Roman auctions. It is not known whether the bidding pro‘
`cedure followed an ascending or a descending pattern, or an entirely
`different one. It
`is
`likely, however,
`that
`the bids increased in
`amount, for the word “auction” is derived from the Latin root
`auezur, “an increase.” Attention was called to a forthcoming auc-
`tion in public announcements made by the praeeo (herald) and
`through a written proscriptio (notice). The praeco, acting as auc-
`tioneer, then put up the lots for sale, stimulated and acknowledged
`bids, and finally “knocked down” each lot to the highest bidder.
`Bidding reportedly took the form of a wink or a nod instead of
`public outcry.3
`Apparently the Romans, when in financial straits, employed the
`auction also in the liquidation of property. Caligula, for example,
`auctioned off the furniture and ornaments belonging to his family to
`help him meet his debts and recoup his losses.4 To cover a state
`deficit, Marcus Aurelius is even said to have held an auction of
`royal heirlooms and furniture which lasted for
`two months.5
`Roman soldiers reportedly put up their loot at auction sub harm, or
`“under the spear.” In fact, the word “subhastation,” now rare, came
`to mean “a public sale or auction.” Because of this practice, Roman
`_ business agents were said to have accompanied military expeditions
`in order to bid in the war booty at public auction.6
`2 I. A. C. Thomas, “The Auction Sale in Roman Law,” Im'idz'crzl Review,
`Pt- I (April, 1957), p- 43-
`3 Ibid.
`4 Tenney Frank, ed., “Rome and Italy of the Empire,” Vol. V of An
`Economic Survey of Ancient Rome (Baltimore: Iohns Hopkins Press, 1940),
`pp. 39—40 n. 12.
`5 Ibid., p. 77.
`6 117121., p. 26 n. 47.
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 5
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 4
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 4
`
`

`

` Historical Perspectives
`
`29
`
` '
`WWIMHWHWIWMWMIMMMWWWWMWMmmmmwhwwmwmmww
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Perhaps the most preposterous auction in history was held in
`193 A.D., when the whole Roman Empire was placed on the block
`by the Praetorian Guard. After having killed the preceding em-
`peror, Pertinax,
`the leaders of the guard announced that
`they
`would bestow the crown upon the Roman who offered the largest
`donation. When Didius Iulianus outbid all his rivals by promising
`each man 6,250 drachmas, the guard declared him emperor. After
`Didius had been in power for only two months, however,
`the
`legions under the command of Septimius Severus seized the capital
`and beheaded the emperor.7
`Even less is known about auctioning in other ancient civiliza—
`tions. In China, four institutions were utilized to raise money for
`Buddhist
`temples and monasteries: pawnshops, mutual financing
`associations,
`lotteries, and auction sales.8 Apparently the personal
`belongings of deceased monks were auctioned 0H as early as the
`seventh century AD. The monk who acted as auctioneer had to
`know the normal price and announce whether the item was new,
`old, or worn out. If bidding went too high, he reminded his fellow
`monks: “Better be thoughtful. You might regret it later.”
`Despite the paucity of information, it is clear from the foregoing
`that the auction was employed as a sales mechanism in ancient
`times. Precise auctioning methods and the extensiveness of their
`use, however, remains shrouded in mystery. All we really know is
`that this way of selling property is not a modern phenomenon, but
`has its origins in antiquity.
`'
`
`Early-Day Auctioning in England
`
`I
`
`It is diflicult, if not impossible, to determine when the auction
`method of selling was first employed in England. The earliest
`reference to the term in the Oxford English Dictionary is dated
`1595, although admittedly this is simply a straw in the wind. It is
`known, however, that toward the end of the seventeenth century
`sellers of pictures frequently met in coffeehouses and taverns to
`
`7 Will Durant, Caesar and Christ, The Story of Civilization, Pt. III (New
`York: Simon and Schuster, 1944), pp. 620—621.
`8 Lien-sheng Yang, “Buddhist Monasteries and Four Money—raising In—
`stitutions in Chinese History,” Harvard [ouraal of Asiatic Studies, XIII (June,
`1950), 174-191‘
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 6
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 5
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 5
`
`

`

`
`
`30
`
`Auctions and Auctioneerz‘ng
`
`auction their wares. A 1682 issue of the London Gazette referred to
`the “daily attendance” at the “Auction-house,” clearly suggesting
`an auction operation. Before such sales, catalogs were often issued.
`The announcement in one of them reads:
`
`. on Thursday 12th Friday
`.
`[The goods] will be exposed to sale .
`13th and Saturday 14th of this instant March, at Mrs. Smythers Coffee
`House in Thames street, by the Custom House: The Sale beginning each
`Morning precisely at Nine of the Clock. The said Paintings are to be
`viewed from this day forward until all be sold. Catalogues may be had at
`the place of sale.
`Pray read me, but do not take me from the Table.9
`Sales of certain types of chattels were also conducted by the auction
`method, at least occasionally, in seventeenth—century England; for
`example, Samuel Pepys witnessed an auction sale of ships in 1662.10
`It may reasonably be assumed that other types of property were
`auctioned as well.
`The firm of Sotheby’s, world—famous auctioneers, was estab—
`lished in 1744, and Christie’s, similarly renowned, had its begin-
`nings in 1766. These firms may, of course, have conducted business
`in other ways than auctioning, and may have been antedated by
`other auction houses of which we have no knowledge. It was
`not until years later that announcements of auctions appeared in
`the public prints, although posted announcements may have been
`prevalent. The oldest English legal action developing from an
`auction of any kind appears to have been Daniel v. Adams, 27
`Eng-Rep; (Amb) 495 (I764)-11
`_
`_
`_
`Little 18 known about the methods of auctioning 1n early-day
`England, but it appears that conditions of sale were as common
`then as they are today. One extant list of eighteenth-century operat-
`ing rules indicates the type of auction employed as well as the terms
`of sale:
`
`9 Quoted in Peter Ash, “The First Auctioneer: Origin of Sales by Auction
`of Real Property,” Estates Gazette (Centenary Supplement), May 3, 1958,
`P 3?) Diary and Correspondence of Samuel Pepys, Esq., F.R.S., with a Life
`and Notes by Richard Lord Braybrooke, Deciphered, with Additional Notes,
`by Rev. Mynors Bright, M. A. (New York: Dodd, Mead, 1887), II, 327.
`II Ash, op. cit, p. 33.
`
`
`
`:7
`,
`
` RAE
`.
`A ,
`Old!
`.
`' {TO
`3.11 i
`pec
`Of %
`fI'Q
`b0?
`
`a (_
`_'
`n0
`W(
`
`Syf
`R:
`Cl,
`ed
`
`a:
`ft
`?
`(3'
`11
`b
`5
`‘0'
`i
`i
`
`::
`f
`
`.2
`37
`-
`:
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 7
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1013. Page 6
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 6
`
`

`

`
`
`Historical Perspective:
`
`31
`
`I. The high bidder is the buyer and, if any dispute arises as to
`which bid is the highest, the goods will be put up for sale again.
`2. No bidder may advance another’s bid by less than sixpence
`when the amount offered is less than £ I, or by less than one shilling
`when the price is ,5 I or more.
`3. The merchandise for sale is warranted as perfect, and before
`removing the goods from the premises any buyer may accept or
`reject them.
`4. Each buyer must give his name and make a deposit of 5 shil-
`lings on each pound sterling (if demanded); no deliveries will be
`made during the sale.
`5. All purchases must be taken away at the buyer’s expense, and
`the amount due must be paid at the place of sale within three days
`after the purchase.
`6. Any would—be buyer who is unable to attend the sale may
`have his commission executed by a representative of the auction
`firm.12
`
`A statement found at the beginning of an early-day catalog may
`throw further light on early English auction operations: “And that
`I may remove the Prejudices of some, and the Misapprehensions of
`others, as to the sincerity of the management, I have printed the
`Conditions of Sale with an additional one,
`that no Person or
`Persons shall be admitted to bid for his, or their own Pictures.
`3) 13
`
`As to the type of auction employed in the eighteenth century, it
`cannot be assumed that
`the English, or ascending, system was
`always used simply because of its prevalence today. Certainly some
`sales were conducted on that basis, as evidenced by the original
`wording of the second rule listed above: “That no Persona advance:
`less than Sixpence each bidding, and after the Book arises to One
`Pound, no less than One Shilling [emphasis added].” 14 There is
`little question, also, that in some early auctions the candle method
`was utilized. For example, Samuel Pepys reported such an auction:
`“After dinner by water to the office, and there we met and sold the
`Weymouth, Successe, and Fellowship hulkes, where pleasant to see
`
`12 Adapted from the original as given in James Brough, Auction! (Indiana-
`polis and New York: Bobbs—Merrill, 1963), pp. 26—27.
`13 Quoted in Ash, op. cit., p. 33.
`I4 Brough, op. cit., p. 26.
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 8
`
`
`
`5%;E}
`iig;
`
`
`
`‘lWWIWWWWWMWWWWWMiwiulwDiWmilWMWWIWNWWWWUiiWMHimwllmlwMlurll:‘NuMWHMNNWWNMWNWW
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 7
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 7
`
`

`

`
`
` frt
`
`AU‘
`E -
`PJJ
`
`551‘
`
`:
`
`"
`015%
`fro .
`in .
`pe<
`of
`
`fl
`‘.
`'
`
`bO‘
`
`'
`
`a I
`_:
`116
`W:
`i
`Sy
`
`Cf
`CC;
`:
`tl
`
`
`
`32
`
`Auction; and Auctianccrz'ng
`
`how backward men are at first to bid; and yet when the candle is
`going out, how theyrbawl and dispute afterwards who bid the most
`first [emphasis added].” 15 This type of auction was evidently the
`English type, with the added feature of an allowance for a specified
`time interval. To a limited extent, it is still used today when speed
`of transaction is not requisite and when it is helpful to buyers to
`know approximately the amount of time they will have to consider
`the maximum amount they wish to bid.
`a
`One
`seventeenth-century catalog mentioned “mineing,”
`“Method of Sale not hitherto used in England,” 16 undoubtedly
`imported from Holland. In this type of auction,
`the auctioneer
`apparently put up each lot at a high price and kept reducing the
`price until someone called “Mine!” In the early British system,
`however, another bidder presumably could advance on the bid, so
`that a blending of the Dutch (descending) system with the English
`(ascending) system would have resulted. The available evidence
`suggests that auction fees were charged on a percentage basis, and
`that they were upward of 5 percent, graduated downward with the
`increase in sales prices.
`Between I660 and 1740 auctions in the form of “peremptory
`sales,” held either by court order or privately, were apparently quite
`common in England. Although the auctioning of chattels seems to
`have preceded the auctioning of land, both types of property were
`offered in an advertisement appearing in the London Evening Post,
`March 8—10, 1739. After listing some merchandise items (including
`threads, sacks, gold and silver lace, and brocaded waistcoats), the
`auctioneer announced that in “the first Day’s Sale will be sold two
`Houses belonging to the said Bankrupt’s Estate, situated at Pad—
`. dington, and adjoining to the Churchyard.” 17 The first announce—
`ment of a sale devoted only to land appeared in the same news—
`paper in the 1740’s. It is not known what method was employed in
`auctions of real property.
`The best evidence is that auctioning of estates in England origi—
`nated with a gentleman named
`
`
`
`Christopher Cock, of the Great Piazza in Covent Garden. This man seems
`to have been a “live—wire.” .
`.
`. We are lucky to possess the Daily Ad—
`
`15 Diary and Correspondence of Samuel Pepys, p. 327.
`I6 Quoted in Ash, of. (1)., p. 33.
`17 Quoted in z'bid., p. 35.
`
`:3
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 9
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 8
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 8
`
`

`

`Historical Perspective:
`
`33
`
`vertiser of April 25, 1735, because it contains the earliest advertisement of
`his I have been able to discover. This announces three chattel sales ”at
`Mr. Cock’s Great Room,
`in the Piazzar, Covent Garden." One of the
`sales was by order of the South Sea Company, and another was a post-
`poned sale of Arabian horses. The contents and style of the advertisement
`make it plain that Cock was already in a very substantial way of business.18
`
`Auctioning in Early-Day America
`
`It might be expected that institutions as well as ideas would
`emigrate with the people who move from one country to another.
`In this way, no doubt, the auction found its way from England to
`America, where from an early date the colonists used this method
`of selling to dispose of property under the judicial process or to close
`out stocks of merchandise. In early—day America the auction was
`used to liquidate capital goods and inventories, to unload unsalable
`goods remaining in importers’ hands at the end of the season, and
`to sell secondhand household furnishings, farm utensils, and d0-
`mestic animals. As auctioning was evidently considered a discredit—
`able way of selling goods, various methods of concealing the
`owner’s name were employed.19
`Use of auctioning by American importers—The use of auction—
`ing in early—day America was widespread, particularly at the pri—
`mary market level.20 As population increased and larger areas of
`the East Coast became settled, auctioning made rapid progress.
`Information is lacking as to which auctioning method was most
`prevalent, although apparently it was the English or ascending-bid
`system.
`In the early eighteenth century, a British manufacturer or ex—
`porter customarily consigned his goods to an agent in some Ameri—
`can port. The agent then bonded the merchandise, landed it in the
`United States, and sold it at auction, usually accepting in payment
`promissory notes which were discounted at banks. The agent then
`would deduct his commission and remit
`the remainder of
`the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`18 117221. For a discussion of early—day auctions in France, see Octave Uzanne,
`“The Hotel Drouot and Auction Rooms in Paris before and after the French
`Revolution,” The Connoisseur, III (Aug, 1902), 235—242.
`19 Ray Bert Westerfield, “Early History of American Auctions: A Chapter
`in Commercial History,” Transactions of the Connecticut Academy of Art:
`
`
`and Sciences, XXIII (May, 1920), I64.
`
`20 Ihz'd., p. 165.
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 10
`
`eBay Ex. 1013. Page 9
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 9
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Aijl
`PU‘
`*
`a,
`fiA]
`
`
`
`.HU)minimum-"wIflflmnmulluwmwwmmrmWindham».-iminim-amuuumnIMm,1“!leDMitnlhmllIhmu“Mutant"IIv”(mumlmun“IuhIIIIIIHIllwfimml-Qmmaimstdmi
`
`
`
`34
`
`Auction: and Auctionccrin g
`
`money to his principal in Britain. The usual procedure in these
`auctions was to exhibit the goods for a day or two prior to the sale,
`giving prospective purchasers a chance to appraise the articles in
`which they were interested and check them off in the catalog pro—
`vided by the auctioneer. Most auction firms of any size held sales
`on two or more days each week.21
`When American ports were closed to direct importations from
`Europe during the War of 1812, British merchants established
`extensive depots of goods in Halifax, Bermuda, and other British
`possessions so that they might be ready to supply the American
`market as soon as peace was declared. After the close of the war,
`the British found auctions the most profitable and the quickest way
`to turn their goods into cash. The market was soon glutted with
`merchandise, and by 1816 prices had fallen so far that they scarcely
`covered the duties.22
`
`As auctioning became prevalent in early—day American com—
`merce, orthodox importers and jobbers were circumvented;
`they
`raised loud cries of protest and began to demand protective legisla—
`tion. To complicate matters, prices were much lower in Britain
`than America, enabling foreign merchants to undermine American
`production and marketing operations by exporting British goods to
`America. The dumping of foreign goods on American markets,
`which was merely expedited by use of the auction method, created
`serious public resentment and culminated in a strong campaign
`against auction sales generally.
`The auction system, however, did have some advantageous
`commercial effects in America. For one thing, auctions facilitated
`the introduction of new foreign and domestic products; goods were
`forced onto the market by the simple expedient of price—cutting,
`and in time the prejudices against the introduction and promotion
`of
`such goods were overcome.23 Auctions also assisted small
`domestic manufacturers to gain a position in the market. Finally,
`merchants and retailers from the interior increasingly patronized
`auction sales in the port cities, especially those in New York, and
`thus made imported items available to inland markets.
`Auctiom'ng of slave: in the Old South—Any historical account
`
`21 117221., pp. 173—177.
`22 15221., p. 165.
`23 111121., p. 18L
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 11
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 10
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 10
`
`

`

`
`
`I,iIvillvIIiI1IvIIHIvrlVlMlIIIIIIIt\IMIMIIAHIIIG‘MVMMWIMWWW-.x'
`
`flWlMWlWllWlIN,WM"Ml|MmILilIlmllIWIWllWMI“IIIIllIIIIl4IullIIIWlMfillIIlIilMlMIIIIIMklnillv-«lly
`
`Historical Perspective:
`
`35
`
`0f auctioning in America would be incomplete without mention of
`the infamous sale of slaves in the Old South before the Civil War.
`At that time slaves were considered as chattels and were sold at
`auction, though occasionally they were bought at a fixed price set
`by the vendor, or after individual negotiation between seller and
`buyer.
`The demand for slaves varied, depending on sex, age, and
`physical condition. Healthy young men were much sought after
`and thus commanded high prices, sometimes as much as $1,750;
`men who were not so young but who had been trained in a trade
`were also very desirable. Women,
`too, were in demand—some as
`mothers of future children, some as servants, and some as fancy
`women. Children were acquired for the purpose of keeping families
`together and as speculative purchases which were expected to pay
`off at a later time.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Slave trading was unrestricted until 1808, when a federal statute
`was passed proscribing the importation of slaves into the United
`States. Up to that time importers offered slaves for sale to plantation
`owners, their agents or brokers, or secondary traders who acquired
`the property for subsequent resale. After 1808, or at least after 1818
`when the penal clauses of the restrictive legislation were strength-
`ened, the primary slave market presumably ceased to exist. Trading
`in slaves did continue, however, among hard—pressed plantation
`owners who had to sell to professional traders,
`the latter were in
`the business of buying slaves and selling them to farmers needing
`additional help or to dealers acquiring the property for resale. After
`the Emancipation Proclamation,
`the slave trade was completely
`outlawed, at least in most jurisdictions.
`‘
`though
`Available descriptions of the slave-auctioning process,
`sketchy, suggest that the English, or ascending—bid, method was
`Used. The auctioneer gave his opening spiel to a “crowd gathered in
`the marketplace, and the first lot, consisting of one person or pos—
`sibly of a whole family, was put up for sale.24 He also made full
`use of the practice of displaying the “merchandise,” even at the cost
`of embarrassing the individual up for sale, and much good—natured
`but often crude banter was engaged in by the crowd. The auc—
`tioneer would suggest an opening bid, but sometimes had to slip
`24 Frederic Bancroft, Slat/e Trading in the Old Sour/z (New York: Fred—
`erick Ungar Publishing Co., 1959), pp. 109—110.
`'
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 12
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 11
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 11
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`36
`
`Auction: and Auctioneering
`
`back in order to obtain a firm offer; after receiving a starting bid he
`would lead the buyers upward, enunciating not only the actual bids
`that were made but the advance he was aiming for.
`When slaves were sold in family groups, the bidding was often
`based on an average price per person. The value placed on the
`father might be $1,200 and that on the mother $950, and three
`children might be valued at $725, $650, and $475, for a total
`estimated family value of $4,000. Actual bids might start at $200 per
`person and move up to approximately $700, or a total of about
`$3,500 for the family. This method of selling multiple units, not
`uncommon today, was undoubtedly adopted because it was ex-
`pected to maximize returns. Not only did it emphasize the smaller
`individual figures instead of the larger total amount, but it placed
`the “value of the best slave in the group .
`.
`. uppermost in the
`bidder’s mind.” 25
`In slave auctioning, when the price approached the maximum
`demand prices of the buyers, it was the practice of the auctioneer to
`narrow the amount of the advance from, say, 50 dollars to 25 t0 IO
`or even 5 dollars. Finally, when it was apparent that bidders had
`about reached their limit, the auctioneer would say “Ah you-all
`done? Seven—hundud—an’——five—dollahsl Once—twice—third—
`an’—lart—-call; goin’, goin’," and then "Sold fo’ SCI/€72 hzmdud an’
`five dolla/zs to Mr. Ienks.” 26 Although the existing superficial de-
`scriptions of American slave auctions give no information about the
`use of a reserve price, it is clear that lots were withdrawn from sale
`When bids were considered unreasonably low.
`
`Latter—Day; Developments in Auctioning
`
`Despite the long tradition of price making by the auction
`method, the use of auctioning is relatively new in many areas and
`fields.
`Netherlands.—The practice of auctioning fruits and vegetables
`in the Netherlands, so prevalent
`today,
`is only eighty years old,
`even though the method had been previously used in other fields
`(for example, the sale of porcelain ware). It was in 1887 that the
`sale of produce by auction first replaced sale by private treaty in
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`25 117121., p. 230.
`26 Ibid., p. III.
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 13
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 12
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 12
`
`

`

`3E
`
`g
`
`E i l 5
`
`%
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`’
`
`1
`1
`l
`
`I
`
`1
`l
`
`“
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 13
`
`”
`
`
`
`Historical Perspective:
`
`37
`
`Holland. Before the days of auctioning, produce dealers would
`either buy from the grower, acquire goods on commission, or make
`advances to producers for crops still
`in the ground. Often the
`grower needed cash advances to enable him to implement cultiva-
`tion, but this practice obviously placed him at a disadvantage in
`relation to the dealer, and “he frequently could do nothing but wait
`passively for the final settlement which might bear no relation to
`current prices.”27 As in certain localities and commodity areas
`today, the distributor controlled the producer.
`In 1887 there occurred a significant event that was to have a
`tremendous effect on the production phase of the industry. One
`midsummer morning a grower by the name of Iongerling arrived
`with his bargeload of vegetables at the quay of the inland harbor
`Brock op Langendijk in North Holland. Here it was customary for
`producers to sell to dealers or to physically transfer the produce for
`sale on a commission, but on this particular morning demand was
`very brisk and the farmer—vendor found it difficult
`to decide to
`which of
`the eagerly competing buyers he should allocate his
`limited supply of goods. A passing boatman reportedly suggested
`that Iongerling put his produce up for sale at auction, which he did
`with gratifying results. Thus it was that the first auction of horti-
`cultural produce in the Netherlands took place. From that
`tiny
`beginning developed the present-day vast
`system of auction
`markets, with all their auxiliary services.28
`.
`Gcrmcmy.—Auctioning of fish developed in Germany at almost
`precisely the same time as auctioning of produce in the Nether-
`lands. Until
`the latter part of
`the nineteenth century, German
`fishermen personally delivered their catches to consumption centers.
`At first they sold the fish themselves, often having to stay in port
`for long periods of time in order to do so; later the middlemen took
`over the selling, thus releasing the fishermen for more productive
`work.
`
`specialization of effort was basically sound,
`Although this
`the distributors frequently took advantage of the absentee owners,
`using their strong position in relation to that of the individual
`
`27 The Auction System of Horticultural Marketing in the Netherlands
`(2d ed.; The Hague: Central Bureau of Horticultural Auctions in the
`Netherlands, 1959), p. 6.
`28 11:121., p. 7.
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 14
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 13
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`:
`
`
`
`3A]
`,
`014 ,_
`”
`,
`€110
`E
`3,1"
`pet
`of
`f“
`b0
`.
`;
`ag
`‘
`DC
`W1
`SS
`R
`G
`,
`CC.
`
`tl
`ft
`
` ii
`
`I
`l
`c
`
`(
`5
`
`E.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`38
`
`Auction: and Auctioneering
`
`fishermen to bring primary market prices down. Sometimes whole
`lots spoiled after fishermen refused to deliver their catches to the
`dealers at the going prices. Eventually, however, a system of firm
`contracts between fishermen and distributors developed, but the sale
`of fish by private treaty was still unsatisfactory.
`Some type of open—market operation was required to establish a
`price that would reflect current and prospective demand and supply
`conditions, and thus eliminate the price-depressing tactics of the
`distributor—buyers. Consequently, the first fish auction took place in
`Hamburg on May 1, I887, when the fishermen sold their catches to
`dealers on a competitive—bid basis.29 Other fish auctions soon fol-
`lowed—in Geestemunde in 1888, in Bremerhaven in 1892, and in
`Cuxhaven in 1908. The Kiel market apparently was not established
`until 1947.
`Iapan.——The problem of distributor-dominated selling of fish by
`private treaty is brought into bold relief by examples from the
`Orient. Until about a century ago, exploitation of Iapanese fisher—
`men by their distributors seems to have been a common, if not
`universal, phenomenon. Under Japan’s feudal organization the
`rulers gave fish merchants a monopoly of marketing, the so—called
`Ura-ukeoi
`system, which intensified the dominance of
`large
`capitalist—distributors over
`scattered small-scale fishermen. The
`favored merchants paid tribute to the overlords as a quid pro quo
`for the exploitation rights they enjoyed.
`The first step in the reform movement came with the collapse of
`feudalism and its monopolistic structure. The process, beginning in
`1869, was accelerated during the period 1910—1930, and formerly
`monopolistic activities were opened to competitive enterprisers. The
`old market system was replaced by keen competition among dealers
`for markets and supplies, which might well have paved the way for
`another type of control—capital advances to fishermen by distribu-
`tOrs in exchange for exclusive purchasing agreements at distributor-
`determined prices during the period of the obligation. Under this
`system, exploitation of the fisherman developed through distributor
`credit control and private—treaty buying and selling negotiations.
`When control over
`suppliers is effected through a debtor-
`
`29 Klaus—Hinrich Krohn and Arnold Alewell, Sea—Fish Mar/(sting in the
`Federal Republic of Germany (Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of
`the United Nations, 1957), p. 105.
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 15
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 14
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 14
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`39
`Historical Perspective:
`
`creditor relationship, there is little or no competition for the goods
`produced; there would exist, in fact, numerous little monopsonies,
`
`or “buying monopoly” situations, for suppliers would be permitted
`
`to trade only with those to whom they owed money. The buyer-
`creditor might be able arbitrarily to set the price and thus gain the
`IIIIIII1umn’unyIIIuIIMImmmummu
`
`advantage not only of keeping supply costs low but of depressing
`prices to fishermen. The latter would find it diflicult, if not impos-
`sible, to extricate themselves from their predicament,30 especially in
`the absence of antitrust laws.
`Not until after World War II was the modern wholesale market
`system established throughout Japan. The key to equitable treat—
`ment of producers by distributors is an open—market system, such as
`the auction, which permits buyers to sell
`their goods at market
`prices and thus prevents exploitation by distributor—buyers.
`In
`Japan,
`the relationship between seller and buyer, an important
`aspect of which is
`the auction system of selling goods at
`the
`primary level, is completely free.
`Hong Kong—Control of the fishermen by the 146112, or middle-
`man, prevailed in the Hong Kong market until just after the ter—
`mination of World War II. The merchant-capitalist provided the
`fishermen with needed supplies and credit and, in return, required
`the fishermen to bring their catches to him, the creditor, until the
`debt was paid—which, of course, might never happen. Legislation
`enacted in the Crown Colony in 1940, however, subsequently led to
`the replacement of 162472 control by self-governing cooperatives.31
`The latter assumed the fishermen’s financial obligations and paid
`OH debts owed the merchant-distributors, many of which had been
`passed on from father to son and might have gone on forever in the
`absence of such legislation.
`The producers were thus free to sell their goods under competi—
`tive market conditions rather than to the monopsonist. This open-
`market mechanism took the form of public auction for the sale of
`fish and, oddly enough, of individual negotiation (bargaining be—
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`30 See Akira Hasegawa and Hirohiko Watanabe, “Distributive System
`
`and Cooperative Marketing of Fishery Products in Japan” (Tokyo: Fisheries
`Research Institute, 1958), mimeographed.
`31 “The Hong Kong Fish and Vegetable Marketing Schemes” (Hong
`
`Kong: Co-operative Development 8: Fisheries Department, Dec., 1962), mimeo—
`
`graphed, p. I.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`eBay Ex. 1007 - App. D, Page 16
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 15
`
`eBay Ex. 1013, Page 15
`
`

`

`
`
`9:!
`
`E2
`
`lunuumwmmmmmw
`
`0
`
`cm
`(—1"h«lg—dummmimmmw
`-—?wv.rfilms....4a
`
`uwfl'mwvflmxwm.”artistsngtr
`
`40
`
`Auction: and Auctioneerin g
`
`in the sale of
`tween the buyer and the cooperative salesman)
`produce. Because all producers were required to distribute their
`goods through the public market, forestalling was precluded. The
`auction had become an effective tool in implementing a progra

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket