throbber
PERSUASION OR INFORMATION?
`
`PROMOTION AND THE SHARES OF
`
`BRAND NAME AND GENERIC
`
`PHARMACEUTICALS*
`
`and
`
`MARK A. HURWITZ
`RICHARD E. CAVES
`Carpomre Decisions. Inc.
`Harvard University
`Ecostomsrs have vigorously debated whether advertising and other
`messages supplied by sellers to buyers represent the efficient provision of
`information or the exploitation of buyers‘ imperfect access to it. Many
`economists now agree that each view commands some truth. Advertising
`should convey information efficiently where the buyer can easily verify it.
`But it may engender inefficient rent—seeking outlays by producers able to
`hamper buyers‘ gaining of information from alternative sources. For ex-
`ample, if buyers sample product information randomly, an incumbent can
`“jam” the channels through which entrants transmit their messages by
`loading the sampled pOpulation with messages of his own.l Or the incum-
`bent‘s messages can reinforce buyers‘ habits so as to reduce their prior
`expectations of the value of trying an alternative brand.2 If sales promo-
`tion is effective (by whatever means) in causing buyers to shift among
`competing products, it becomes a form of rent-seeking outlay by which
`sellers bid for the available customers.3 The problem for empirical re-
`search is to determine the extent to which seller—supplied information
`pursues a rent-seeking goal and thus incurs social costs. Those costs must
`be set against the efficiency advantage of sellers (relative to buyers or
`
`* We are grateful to Dennis Carlton and a referee for suggestions and to Heng-fu Zou for
`research assistance.
`
`' William S. Comanor. The Political Economy of the Pharmaceutical industry. 24 J.
`Econ. Literature 1178 ([986). at [191 and references cited therein.
`2 Richard Schmalensee‘ Product Differentiation Advantages of Pioneering Brands. 72
`Am. Econ. Rev. 349 ([982]. Some evidence on the incidence ofinformative and rent—seeking
`outlays in sales promotion is provided by Richard E. Caves. Information Structures of
`Product Markets. 24 Econ. Inquiry 195 (1986}.
`3 See. for example. Sherwin Rosen, Advertising. Information, and Product Differentia—
`tion. in Issues in Advertising: The Economics of Persuasion l6l, [77—82 (David G. Tuerck
`ed.
`[978).
`[Journal ofLow & Ecoriomics. Vol. XXXI (October 1988)]
`© 1988 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-2186f88f3102-0002$01.50
`
`299
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 1
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 1
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`300
`
`THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`third parties) as suppliers of product information demanded by buyers—
`as Leffler put it, persuasion or information.‘
`The pharmaceutical industry provides a strategic site for testing hy-
`potheses about
`the scope of rent seeking in manufacturers‘
`sales-
`promotion outlays. Obviously. physicians who prescribe drugs must ac-
`quire extensive information about
`the uses and limitations of new
`pharmaceuticals. The manufacturer who must generate the bulk of this
`information in the course of developing a drug has both the opportunity
`and the incentive to disseminate it efficiently while the drug enjoys patent
`protection. When the patent expires the innovator‘s trademark lives on,
`but competitors may arise to offer the generic drug at discount prices. The
`incumbent may sustain its position against such rivals both by current
`outlays on promotion to jam the entrants’ information channels and by
`anticipatory investments to enlarge the goodwill asset of its trademarked
`brand. Prescribers’ weak incentives for selecting the lowest-price brand
`enhance the payout to such policies. The physician who prescribes a drug
`on the basis of seller—supplied information captures no savings from
`selecting a cheaper generic supplier (these savings seem too small to
`attract patients away from other physicians], so that the price elasticity
`of demand for the branded drug is reduced, and the innovator obtains
`something approximating the advantage of pioneering brands modeled
`by Schmalensee.5
`For a sample of drugs that have gone off—patent and encountered ge-
`neric competition, we address a series of questions about rivalry in sales
`promotion and pricing between the innovators and the generic entrants.
`I.
`Is the entrants‘ market share adversely affected by the innovator’s
`accumulated goodwill asset or by his ongoing sales-promotion outlays?
`2. How effective are the generics1 sales-promotion outlays and price
`discounts in eroding the innovator’s market share?
`3. How is this rivalry affected by the passage of time—the number of
`years in which the innovator enjoyed a monopoly and the number of years
`since generics first invaded the market?
`4. Is the generics1 competition less effective (and are innovators‘ de—
`fenses more effective) in the pharmacy than in the hospital market, where
`incentives to minimize costs operate more strongly?
`the
`in Section I‘
`Before presenting the design in detail we review,
`evidence of the pharmaceuticals market’s susceptibility to rent-seeking
`sales promotion and characterize the resulting opportunity for dynamic
`
`“ Keith B. Leffler. Persuasion or Information? The Economics of Prescription Drug Ad—
`vertising, 24 J. Law & Econ. 4?—48 (1981}.
`5 Schmalensee, supra note 2.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 2
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 2
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PROMOTION OF PHARMACEUTICALs
`
`301
`
`optimization by the innovator. Section II outlines the statistical model,
`evaluates the results, and reports tests of several corollary hypotheses.
`Section III relates our findings to recent changes in public policy toward
`pharmaceutical innovators and their competitors.
`
`1. CHARACTERtsths OF THE PHARMACEUTICALS MARKET
`
`We review evidence on the positions of pharmaceutical innovators,
`entrant producers of generic drugs, and health professionals in order to
`show the role of sales-promotion activities in the decisions made by each
`group.
`
`Producers of Branded Phormacemicais
`
`A pharmaceutical firm that acquires a patent on a new ethical drug
`becomes a temporary monopolist who knows when its legal protection
`against entrants will expire. Theoretical analyses of such monopolists‘
`behavior have stressed their scope for maximizing wealth by building a
`goodWill asset while entry is precluded and by responding optimally to
`entry When it occurs. If the monopoly holds no durable goodwill asset, its
`position When legal protection lapses becomes no different from that of
`new entrants to the market (scale economies and sunk costs permitting).
`If the monopoly holds a durable but wasting goodwill asset, or if the rate
`of newcomers’ entry is constrained, the monopoly enjoys strategic op-
`tions in the postpatent period that boil down to ceding market share to
`entrants at a rate that maximizes the terminal value of its goodwill asset.°
`During the period of our study, by the time a patented drug was ap-
`proved by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration for marketing.
`its
`developer typically had about half of its seventeen-year patent protection
`left as a period of legal monopoly? However, the developer gains perma-
`nent monopoly of a trademark name that becomes the vehicle for a dur-
`able goodwill asset. Thus, any given drug (like T. S. Eliot‘s cat) has three
`different names, One, the chemical name, describes the product‘s molec—
`
`° This large literature includes both theoretical models such as Darius W. Gaskins, IL,
`Dynamic Limit Pricing: Optimal Pricing under Threat of Entry. 3 J. Ec0n. Theory 306
`([971]; and empirical tests such as Robert T. Masson & Joseph Shaanan1 Stochastic—
`Dynamic Limit Pricing: An Empirical Test, 64 Rev. Econ. Stat. 413 (1982}.
`’ Mean-effective patent life had declined from about sixteen years in the mid-19605 to
`seven to nine years after [978. See Richard A. Spivey & A. Gene Trimble, Effect ofthe Drug
`Price Competition Acton Market Exclusivity of New Drugs: A Simulation, 20 Drug infor-
`mation J. 27(1986]. Although drugs on patent are sometimes licensed to another company or
`soldjointly by two companies as part ofa dual marketing arrangement, most drug products
`sold by their innovators do not encounter competition until the patent expiration date.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 3
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 3
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`302
`
`THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND economics
`
`ular structure to scientists. The generic name is a shorter, simpler version
`of the chemical name and is not protected by a trademark. The brand
`name assigned by the developer and given trademark protection is typi-
`cally shorter and easier to remember than the generic name.
`The pharmaceutical industry promotes its products heavily. For many
`research-based firms the promotion budget can be twice to four times as
`large as the budget for research and development, with sales promotion
`running 20 to 30 percent of sales.8 The most heavily used form of promo-
`tion consists of visits to physicians, pharmacists, and other health-care
`professionals by sales representatives of the producers of branded phar—
`maceuticals. Almost 70 percent of the pharmaceutical industry‘s promo—
`tional budget is spent on personal promotion, known as “detailing.” An-
`other 2? percent is spent on advertising in the many journals addressed to
`physicians, who receive on average between seven and twentyjournals a
`month.9 Direct mail accounts for the balance of measured promotional
`outlays. A number of activities of pharmaceuticals firms are geared less
`toward promoting a specific drug than enhancing the general reputation of
`the company. These include textbooks, audiovisual aids, and lectures and
`seminars sponsored as part ofcontinuing medical education for physicians.
`There is evidence that the goodwill asset built up for a patented drug
`substantially outlasts the patent protection. Bond and Lean examined the
`development of two therapeutic markets, orally effective diuretics and
`antianginals. In each, the first firm to offer a new product was able to
`maintain a substantial market share despite entry into the therapeutic
`class of other drugs that were priced lower and promoted more heavily,
`although late entrants tended to be more successful when their brands
`offered some therapeutic novelty.IO
`After the patent’s expiration, sales-promotion outlays and other differ-
`entiation strategies remain open to branded producers. Certain qualitative
`strategies of product differentiation are especially useful in the postpatent
`period. The delivery system—the system required to deliver medication
`to the part of the body where a therapeutic effect is desired—is a common
`element of product differentiation. Differentiated oral dosage forms in-
`
`” Drug Product Selection. Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission, Bureau of
`Consumer Protection 32 (1979]; Comanor, supra note 1, at [196.
`9 Drug Product Selection, supra note 8, at 58.
`‘0 Ronald S. Bond & David F. Lean, Sales, Promotion, and Product Differentiation in
`Two Prescription Drug Markets, Staff Report, Bureau of Economics, U.S. Federal Trade
`Commission ([977). The value of these goodwill aSsets is also confirmed by the evidence that
`most (excess) profits earned by the pharmaceutical industry are due to new drugs. See
`Martin N. Baily, Research and Development Costs and Returns: The U.S. Pharmaceutical
`Industry, 80 J. Pol. Econ. T0 ([972].
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 4
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 4
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PROMOTION OF PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`303
`
`clude time-release capsules and enteric coated pills. Taste can be an
`important factor, particularly tO ensure patient compliance. Differentia—
`tion in packaging, such as the provision of prepackaged unit doses and
`special packaging to fit hospitals‘ dispensing units, provides an additional
`opportunity for protecting the market for patent-lapsed products. The
`appearance of a trademarked pill apparently can be protected from imita-
`tion by an entrant; furthermore, the branded manufacturer can form its
`pill in a shape that is linked to the registered trade name.
`
`Producers of Generic Drugs
`
`The new producer of a drug is foreclosed from using the discoverer’s
`trademarked name but can choose between promoting its own brand
`name (Often an amalgam Of the generic name and the name of the prO~
`ducer] or simply offering the drug under its generic name. While some of
`the larger producers of “commodity“ generics promote the names of their
`companies, most do not.
`Drug innovators face price-inelastic demands and accordingly set
`prices markedly in excess of marginal costs. ” Entrants therefore have the
`opportunity to quote prices that exceed their marginal costs while offering
`large discounts from the patent holder‘s price. Discounts average at least
`20 percent and may leave generics’ prices to final consumers as much as
`two-thirds below the original branded drug’s.‘2 While small retail phar—
`macies usually pay prices close to the published list, prices paid by phar—
`macy chains or buying groups, health maintenance organizations, hospi-
`tals, and other large buyers, such as governments, can vary widely. Both
`brand and generic manufacturers sell their products to hospitals at dis-
`counted prices that can fall as low as 25 percent of prices to pharmacies.
`Bid and group purchasing by hospitals can dramatically lower the prices
`paid for pharmaceuticals.I3 Thus, price differentials selected by entrant
`generic producers and responses by the developers of branded drugs
`
`11 The evidence confirms our expectation that new drug products with any therapeutic
`novelty set prices that are high relative to their established competitors in the therapeutic
`class, but these relative prices drop over the next few years. See W. Duncan Reekie, Price
`and Quality Competition in the United States Drug Industry, 26 J. Indus. Econ. 223 (1973}-
`” In our own sample (described below) the average discount for generics at wholesale is
`56 percent. Prices vary among entrants, with branded generics and products of the larger
`manufacturers carrying premia over the smaller generic companies. A [980 sample of thirty—
`seven multisource drugs found retail prescription prices for generics to average 24 percent
`lower. See Alison Masson 8: Robert L. Steiner, Generic Substitution and Prescription Drug
`Prices: Economics Effects of State Drug Product Selection Laws 36 (1985).
`[3 A [978 study showed that nineteen multisource products were on average 31 percent
`less expensive when purchased by bid. See Frost & Sullivan, Generic Drugs, [OS—4(191r'9).
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 5
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 5
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`304
`
`THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`represent one form of strategic interaction once a patent lapses. The
`available evidence suggests that sequences of pricing moves associated
`with expiring patents are diverse, with branded producers making antici-
`patory price cuts in some cases and declining to match entrants‘ prices in
`others.”
`
`Whether drugs made by branded and generic producers are equivalent
`in quality is an important and controversial issue. The method used by
`medical researchers to compare the quality of chemically identical drugs
`is that of measuring their “bioavailability,” or how much of the drug‘s
`active ingredient gets into the bloodstream and to the site of therapeutic
`action, and at what rate. Two chemically identical drugs that have ap-
`proximately equal bioavailability are said to be bioequivalent. If they are
`equally effective in treating a particular disease, they are said to be thera-
`peutically equivalent. The U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA), in
`its bioavailabilityi’bioequivalence regulations of 1977, established criteria
`to identify products subject to bioequivalence problems and developed
`procedures by which manufacturers of such earmarked products must
`demonstrate their equivalence. Authorities in the field of biopharmaceu-
`tics, contacted by the U. S. Federal Trade Commission (FTC}, believed
`that the criteria used by the FDA to develop its list of problem drugs
`represent the best possible scientific judgment currently available. The
`FDA itself concluded that “there is no substantial evidence of significant
`differences, either in bioavailability or general quality (in terms of purity,
`potency, or other methods of quality control) between brand-name and
`unbranded products, or between products made by large and small manu—
`facturers.” '5 Although the FDA’s list of approved drug products provides
`information regarding the therapeutic equivalence of virtually all prescrip—
`tion drugs, it is not the only source of this information. Preseribers can
`draw on many other nonpromotional sources ofinformation on the quality
`of competing products.
`A separate issue from average product quality is that of quality control
`
`1‘ David Schwartzman, Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry 296—98 (1976}, Meir
`Statman, The Effect of Patent Expiration on the Market Position of Drugs, in Drugs and
`Health: Economic [ssues and Policy Objectives 140(Robert B. Helms ed. [98]). A Canadian
`study suggests that branded drugs‘ prices are typically unresponsive, but that may reflect
`special circumstances; see James J. McRae & Francis Tapon, Some Empirical Evidence on
`Post—patent Barriers to Entry in the Canadian Pharmaceutical Industry, 4 J. Health Econ. 43
`(1985). Theoretically, the wealth-maximizing price differential maintained by the original,
`branded producer could either increase or decrease over time following entry, with increase
`possible if the more price—sensitive buyers are the first to switch to cheaper generics, so that
`the elasticity of substitution fails as generics’ share increases. The more likely sounding case
`of a declining margin between generic and branded drugs would result if the elasticity of
`substitution increases over time or if the time-rate of entry of new producers is constrained.
`‘5 Drug Product Selection, supra note 8, at 245, 256.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 6
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 6
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PROMOTION OF PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`305
`
`and manufacturing practice. Schwartzman urged that there are theoretical
`reasons why smaller generic producers might invest less in quality control
`than larger producers of numerous branded drugs.” The FDA finds pro—
`portionally more problems with recalls and failed inspections among the
`smallest producers; however. the evidence from laboratory tests on final
`products does not clearly weigh against generics.” There is no evidence
`that generics‘ clinical performance is at all affected by differences in
`quality control.
`
`Health Professionals
`
`The key choices of drugs are typically made by physicians, who pre-
`scribe drugs to their patients and leave the actual dispensing to retail or
`hospital pharmacists. When writing a prescription for a multisource drug,
`the physician can prescribe it by either the brand or the generic name. The
`physician has no substantial economic incentive to choose the IOWer—
`priced product, and doctors tend to be ignorant of specific drug prices.
`The brand name, simpler than the generic name, was learned when the
`drug was introduced and is easier to remember, and habit accordingly
`plays a strong role in the physician‘s prescription practice.is
`There is also the question of physicians‘ perceptions of the qualities of
`branded and generic drugs. Surveys indicate that physicians place less
`faith in the quality control of generic than of branded producers; almost
`half of those surveyed disagreed with a statement that small generic
`manufacturers maintain quality—control standards equal to those of brand
`name companies. Escalating malpractice suits have prompted risk-averse
`physicians to prescribe higher—priced brands that are trusted on the basis
`of experience or reputation rather than risking an ineffective treatment or
`adverse reaction from a poor-quality drug. Accordingly, it is no surprise
`that the rate of generic prescribing is low, with 11.6 percent of all pre-
`scriptions filled by retail pharmacists in 1978, rising only to 14.7 percent in
`1983.“31
`
`‘6 Schwartzman, supra note [4, at 215—23. Quality control is likely to entail a substantial
`element of fixed cost, and the smaller or specialized producer has less to lose from negative
`goodwill.
`” Schwartzman, supra note 14, at 226—46.
`18 Drug Product Selection, supra note 8, at 63, I54. Accordingly, Masson & Steiner. supra
`note II, at 89, 101, found the form of the physician‘s prescription pad the strongest
`identifiable determinant of whether generic substitution is permitted in a prescription. Also
`see Henry G. Grabowski & John M. Vernon, Substitution Laws and Innovation in the
`Pharmaceutical Industry, 43 Law & Contemp. Probs. 43 (19%)}.
`‘9 Pharmacy Times Annual Survey, based on data from [MS America. Most brand name
`drug producers (and only some generic producers) offer to pay for damages incurred as a
`result of properly prescribing their products.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 7
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 7
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`306
`
`THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`The retail pharmacist’s role in the selection of drug products has been
`increasing as physicians write more generic prescriptions and as states
`have repealed antisubstitution laws that used to make it illegal to substi-
`tute a generic copy for a prescription that specifies a brand name.10 Phar-
`macists' training prepares them to make choices among chemically identi—
`cal products, but their incentives for minimizing cost to the consumer also
`are not necessarily strong. To the extent that pharmacies1 retail prices
`involve fixed percentage markups, their incentives run contrary to filling a
`prescription at the lowest cost. In 1979, laws in nineteen states required
`that the whole saving from utilizing a generic drug be passed along to the
`customer.ll Perfect competition among pharmacies in supplying well-
`informed buyers would of course insure resorting to generics whenever
`the prescription permits and the buyer wishes; however, shopping costs
`for customers with other than chronic needs surely limit this competitive
`force.22 Perhaps as a result, pharmacists‘ substitution of generic for
`branded drugs, where this is permitted by the prescription, has risen only
`to approximately 16 percent of eligible prescriptions.23
`When drugs are prescribed and dispensed in hospitals, the incentives
`and informational capabilities Ofthe various actors differ from those in the
`case of drugs sold by retail pharmacies. The hospital formulary system is
`based on a contract between the physician and the hospital by which the
`physician agrees that prescriptions written under a brand name shall be
`interpreted as if they were written generically, unless the physician indi—
`cates otherwise. The hospital pharmacist is encouraged to prescribe those
`products listed on the hospital’s formulary. The formulary is a continu-
`ously revised list of drug products approved by the hospital‘s pharmacy
`and a therapeutic committee consisting of pharmacy, clinical, and nursing
`staff members.“ This system pools information on the cost and effec-
`
`1a Physicians may indicate on the prescription form that no substitution may be made for
`a branded drug; the degree to which the form facilitates this (and also the frequency with
`which it is done] varies from state to state. Drug Product Selection, supra note 8, at [ST—90.
`11 Drug Product Selection, supra note 8, at 13‘7—82.
`22 As of19T9,twenty‘twO states required the pharmacist to notify the patientofasubstitu-
`tion, and seventeen recognized the patient‘s right to veto it. Drug Product Selection, supra
`note 8, at [68. Surveys ofconsurners‘ attitudes toward generics give inconsistent results but
`suggest that they are not well informed and may associate higher price with higher quality.
`23 Masmn & Steiner, supra note 20, at 30—32, projected this figure for 1984. They showed
`(at 37—40) why pharmacists‘ markups should be higher on generic than branded prescrip—
`tions, as their average data confirm. See also J. P. Gagnon & C. A. Rodowskas, Reimburse-
`ment Methods for Pharmaceutical Service, [4 .I. Am. Pharmaceutical Soc. 675 (l9'i'4).
`2“ In 1982 the formulary system was in effect in 90.3r percent of U.S. hospitals. Michael H.
`Stolar, National Survey of Hospital Pharmaceutical Services—4982, 40 Am. J. Hospital
`Pharmacy 966 (I983). Leffler, supra note 4, at 53—54, noted the unimportance of sales
`promotion in the hospital markets.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 8
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 8
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PROMOTION CIF PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`307
`
`tiveness of different drugs and helps hospitals to minimize drug costs.
`Furthermore, hospitals and other inpatient facilities have come under
`substantial pressure to minimize costs. Public and third-party payers with
`an interest in cost minimization cover 8?. percent of hospitals' drug expen-
`ditures.25
`
`The federal government, the largest third-party purchaser of pharma-
`ceuticals, employs the Maximum Allowable Cost (MAC) program, which
`limits reimbursements for a multisource drug under federally funded pro-
`grams, such as Medicaid, to the lowest price at which a generically mar-
`keted drug is widely available to pharmacists. Many states have programs
`of their own similar to MAC. These programs significantly increase ge—
`neric substitution by pharmacists.26
`
`Conclusions
`
`While this evidence identifies some factors that have shifted to enhance
`
`the market access of generic entrants, overall it confirms the importance
`of information costs and constraints for competition in the pharmaceutical
`market. We therefore proceed to the test, outlined in this article’s in—
`troduction, of the interdependence of incumbents‘ postpatent market
`shares, sales-promotion outlays, and pricing decisions and their joint de-
`pendence on the drug’s customer base and the type of therapy for which it
`is used. Because the evidence reviewed in this section suggests that
`branded-drug shares should be more difficult to preserve in the hospital
`market than in the retail pharmacy market, we also test whether branded-
`drug shares are less sensitive to their advertising outlays in the hospital
`market.
`
`11.
`
`STATISTICAL MODEL
`
`We constructed a sample by drawing from a list of 150 drug products
`that are available as generics but were originally subject to patents held by
`the firms that developed them.27 Products not available in oral dosage
`forms were eliminated in order to observe products that are widely avail—
`able in both hospitals and pharmacies. A sample of twenty-nine separate
`
`93 W. M. Allen, Prospective—Payment Systems: The Process Becomes Reality, 4 Pharma—
`ceutical Executive 56 (May [984).
`
`’5 Masson & Steiner, supra note [2, at 53—54, 104. The effect of similar programs in
`Canada on branded producers‘ abilities to sustain both high share and high prices was shown
`by McRae & Tapon. Supra note 14.
`’7 In some cases branded products were initially marketed simultaneously by two firms
`due to cross licensing or dual marketing arrangements. We assumed that these partners
`could be regarded as joint monopolists during the patent period; data for the two were
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 9
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 9
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`308
`
`THE JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS
`
`multisource drug markets was obtained, seven of which are among the top
`twenty-five generically prescribed drugs. Because we are interested in
`observing drug markets at varying numbers of years after their patents
`have expired, as many as possible of these drug markets were observed in
`both 1978 and 1983, providing a sample of fifty-six observations.
`
`Variables to Be Explained
`
`Two variables are to be explained in the following analysis: the market
`share held by the original patent holder (hereafter the “leading firm") and
`the ratio of that firm’s sales promotion of the drug to the value of its sales.
`In order to calculate the former, we had to address the problem of the
`diverse strengths and dosage forms in which drugs are typically marketed.
`We chose to measure the market share in physical units—number of pills
`sold by the leading firm divided by total pills sold. Because of large price
`differentials between the leader’s and others“ products, a physical mea-
`sure is clearly preferable to a share of dollar sales. However, it is also not
`appropriate to combine doses marketed in different forms and strengths,
`because (for one reason] the FDA‘s information on equivalency pertains
`only to pills of identical dosage form and strength. When a preliminary
`analysis of the data indicated that market shares of different dosage forms
`of the same product do not differ significantle the decision was made not
`to consolidate sales data for different dosage forms and strengths. In-
`stead, we selected the most popular dosage form (the one that had the
`highest dollar sales for the greatest number of producers) and con
`solidated only different package sizes for that dosage before determining
`the leader‘s market share.28 The variable is designated SHARE.
`The other variable to be explained is promotion of the drug by the
`leading firm in the year in question. A firm‘s sales—promotion outlay was
`calculated as dollars spent on detailing, medical-journal advertising, and
`direct-mail advertising. We secured this outlay for each drug product for
`both the leading firm and (as an exogenous variable—see below) the
`aggregate of other sellers.” The leader‘s outlay was divided by that firm‘s
`
`pooled, and they were treated jointly as the leading brand. The list was taken from Frost &
`Sullivan, supra note 13, at 48. It is worth noting that many off-patent drugs are not chal-
`lenged by entrants—thirty—four of fifty-two in the sample of Henry Grabowski 8t John
`Vernon, Longer Patents for Lower Imitation Barriers: The 1984 DrUg Act, ”l6 Am. Econ.
`Rev. Papers & Proc. 195 (1986).
`2” Sales data were obtained from the U.S. Pharmaceutical Market Drugstore and Hospital
`Audits, published by [MS America, Ltd. [MS estimates sales through a nationwide audit of
`retail drugstores and hospitals, the results of which are validated by comparison with factory
`shipments figures.
`19 Data were obtained from the National Detailing, Journal, and Mail Audits published by
`[MS America, Ltd. [MS estimates detailing expenditures by surveying a sample of physi-
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 10
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2288, pg. 10
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PROMOTION OF PHARMACEUTICALS
`
`309
`
`total sales of the drug (in all dosage forms) to obtain the variable AD-
`SALES.
`
`Exogenous Variables Aflecting Share
`
`Our Specification of models to explain SHARE and ADSALES fOIIOWs
`the same general strategy as other studies ofthis type30 but with variables
`selected and specified to reflect the particular features of drug markets.
`Our model of SHARE is based on the assumption that demand for each
`type ofa drug—leader‘s brand or generic substitute—decreases with own
`price and rivals” promotional expenditures and increases with rivals‘ price
`and own promotion. When those demand functions are consolidated to
`explain SHARE, we expect it to depend on the relative price, expressed
`as the prOportional price discount offered by competing producers
`(PRDIF). To calculate PRDIF we obtained the weighted average invoice
`price paid by drugstores to their suppliers for the leading firm’s pills (PL),
`the median of the average prices paid by drugstores for generic pills (PF).
`and calculated PRDIF 2 (PL — PFUPF.31 Sales—promotion outlays by the
`leader (LPROM) and by all competing suppliers (FPROM) enter the
`model, however‘ not as a ratio but as logarithms of the respective dollar
`amounts. Because the leader‘s and rivals‘ sales—promotion dollars may
`not be equally effective in their influence on market share, we allow them
`to take different coefficients. Furthermore,
`this specification as loga—
`rithms of absolute amounts (not normalized) is appropriate for a cross—
`section sample of pharmaceuticals because all drugs in the sample are
`promoted to essentially the same market of prescribers.32
`Several variables capture the extent of brand loyalty built up by the
`
`cians and collecting data on visits made by sales representatives and minutes spent per drug.
`The figures are transformed to dollars by spreading an estimate of cost per call over the
`minutes spent for each drug. Thejournal audit analyzes 350 publications for advertisements
`and uses published rates to determine expenditures. The mail audit analyzes mailings re,
`ceived by a sa

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket