throbber
THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS
`Volume XLVIII
`September 2000
`
`0022- i 821
`No. 3
`
`THE IMPORTANCE OF DOCTORS’ AND PATIENTS’
`PREFERENCES IN THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION*
`
`ANDREA CoscaLLi’r
`
`This paper studies the contribution of doctor and patient ‘habit‘ to
`persistence in market shares in prescription drug markets. My unique
`panel dataset allows me to estimate the probability of switching brands
`as a function of patient and doctor attributes, with an emphasis on
`past prescribing behaviour so as to capture the degree of persistence. I
`find significant evidence of time—dependence in prescription choices
`for both doctors and patients, which seems to imply that in molecular
`submarkets in which brands are not allowed to compete on the basis of
`price, doctor and patient ‘habit‘ at the micro—level can translate into
`sticky and persistent market shares at the aggregate level.
`
`1.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`{N THIS PAPER, I study the contribution of doctor and patient ‘habit’ to
`persistence in market shares among therapeutically equivalent prescription
`drugs. While, similar issues have arisen in the recent literature about the
`competition between generic and branded drugs,
`they are especially
`puzzling in the Italian pharmaceutical market.
`in Italy, regulatory fiat
`imposes uniform prices across all vendors of drugs which utilize the same
`active ingredient, thus eliminating price variation as an important avenue
`of differentiation among otherwise therapeutically equivalent drugs, which
`is true in drug markets with generic competitors. My unique panel dataset
`allows me to estimate the probability of switching brands as a function
`of patient and doctor attributes, with an emphasis on past prescribing
`behaviour so as to capture the degree of persistence.
`This analysis can shed, light on several aspects of market structure in
`the pharmaceutical industry. First, there is a growing body of literature
`
`from the European Commission through a TMR
`*I acknowiedge financial support
`fellowship #ERBFMBICT972232. i would liite to thank the Istituto Superiore dz‘ Saniza’ for
`the use of their data. This paper was previously circulated under the title ‘Are Market Shares
`in Drug Markets Affected by Doctors’ and Patients‘ i’relerences for Brands?'. Seminar
`participants at Stanford University (GSB and Department of Economics), Royal Holloway
`and UCL have provided valuable comments.
`I would like to especially thank my principal
`adviser, Peter Reiss, who constantly helped me improve this paper, and the editor David
`Genesove for his useful comments. Mike Mazzeo, Fiona Scott Morton, Andrea Shepard,
`Matthew Shum and an anonymous referee have also provided many useful suggestions. All
`errors, however, are my own.
`1'Anthor‘s affiliation: National Economic Research Associates, l5 Stratford Place, London
`W] N QAF, UK.
`email: Andrea. Cosceiii@nem. com
`o Blackwell Publishers {.112000. :05 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 15?. UK. and 130 Main Slrccl. Malden. MA 02143. USA.
`349
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 1
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 1
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`350
`
`ANDREA COSCELLI
`
`that tries to explain observed market segmentation using data on national
`market shares. Empirical observations of market shares for trade—name
`and generic drugs in post—patent therapeutic categories in the US market
`usually indicate a degree of segmentation between branded drugs and their
`generic equivalents, arising from a finite cross~price elasticity between the
`two types of drugs (the cross~price elasticity between two homogeneous
`goods should he infinite), However,
`these studies
`ignore individual
`heterogeneity. The micro dataset at hand allows me both (i) to control for
`individual heterogeneity and (ii) to explore the degree of time-dependence
`in drug choices, both of which can be important
`in explaining the
`substantial and persistent differences in market shares among therapeuti—
`cally equivalent drugs.
`Second, in recent years, We have witnessed a surge in direct advertising
`to consumers by pharmaceutical companies for prescription drugs sold in
`the US market. The amount spent on direct-to—consumer prescription drug
`advertising rose from US$35m in 1987 to US$357m in 1995, US$610m in
`1996, and over US$1 billion in 1997 (NERA [1999]). This spending choice
`reflects a widespread belief within the pharmaceutical
`industry that
`patients should have a role in the choice of prescription drugs. This paper
`directly studies the patient’s role in pharmaceutical choice.
`Finally, the most important institutional features of the Italian market
`during the sample period such as the important role of licensed products,
`limited patient co—payrnents, and lack of direct financial
`incentives to
`doctors to prescribe cheaper drugs characterize almost every EU country
`(NERA [1999]).
`I use a new panel dataset provided by the italian National Health
`Institute, which includes all the prescriptions in the anti-ulcer market from
`i990~1992 for a 10% random sample of the population of Rome aged
`1585. This dataset allows researchers a glimpse into the dynamics of
`prescription behavior at the micro level which is not possible with the
`predominantly aggregate and/ or crosswsectional datasets which have been
`used in most studies of pharmaceutical markets to date.
`My main conclusions are as follows. I begin by testing the null hypo—
`thesis of whether doctors and/or patients are indifferent between dr'fibrent
`brands of the some molecule, as we would expect given their therapeutic
`equivalence. After reiecting the hypothesis, I attempt to isolate both the
`patient—level and the doctor—level factors which are responsible for product
`differentiation.
`I focus specifically on the degree of time-dependence in
`doctors’ and patients’ drug choices by testing whether the patients show
`state dependence in their purchasing patterns, and whether the doctors
`exhibit habit persistence, I find significant evidence of doctor and patient
`‘habit’, which imply that in molecular sub markets in which brands are not
`allowed to compete on the basis of price, habit persistence at the micro~
`
`(it Blackwell Fublishers Ltd. 2600.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 2
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 2
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PREFERENCES as ran PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`
`35E
`
`level can translate into sticky and persistent market shares at the aggregate
`level.
`
`The paper is organized as follows. In the next section I survey the
`previous empirical literature. In Section ill, I describe the dataset used in
`the estimation. Section IV describes my empirical specification, while
`Section V reviews the results. A summary of the results make up the final
`section.
`
`it. Decreas’ DEMAND
`
`While the present study focuses on doctors’ demand for pharmaceutical
`products, most of the recent literature on pharmaceuticals (for example,
`Caves er a1. [l99i}, Caves and Hurwitz {1988}, Berndt er al. [1997], Scott
`Morton [1997, 2000}, and Scherer {I993D has focused on supply-side issues
`(cg, entry, pricing, advertising, R&D races). In his comment on Caves
`er
`a1.
`[1991}, Fakes E199i} argues
`that a panel
`following doctors’
`prescriptions over time would be the only way to understand the major
`determinants of the demand for pharmaceuticals. The panel data 1 use
`allow me to separately identify doctor and patient effects.
`Much of the previous work on the demand for pharmaceuticals has used
`aggregate, market—share data, which are much better suited to measuring
`the degree of differentiation between various drugs rather than explain its
`causes. For example, Stern [1995]
`finds low substitutability between
`branded and generic drugs, while Ellison er a1. [1997} find a high elasticity
`of substitution between generic and branded drags.
`One recent microdata-based analysis of the demand for pharmaceuticals
`is that by Hellerstein {1998]. She focuses on doctors’ choices between
`branded and generic versions of drugs for which a patent has recently
`expired. Significantly, she finds some evidence of habit persistence in the
`prescription behavior of physicians, even after centrolling for observable
`characteristics of physicians and patients. Unfortunately, her dataset does
`not allow her to test for patients’ effects owing to data limitations, while
`her dataset allows for an analysis of financial incentives due to third-party
`payer variation. My dataset, on the other hand, has multiple observations
`for doctor~patient interactions, prescription oi" the same molecule by a
`single doctor to many patients, and prescriptions of the same drug by
`many doctors.
`I987] analyzes competition between patent holders
`Gorecki
`[1986,
`and licensees in Canada: an institutional setting very similar to the
`Italian market. He only observes aggregate data, but he is able to take
`advantage of the regulatory variation among Canadian provinces to
`identify
`competitive
`effects
`in
`his
`empirical
`analysas. Gorecki’s
`conclusions in [1986] are consistent with my results: ‘. .. Since physicians
`still write, by and large, brand name prescriptions for the pioneering
`(13> Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2060.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 3
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 3
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`352
`
`ANDREA COSCELLI
`
`brand, unless an element of price competition is introduced at the level of
`the pharmacist the pioneering brand wilt continue to dominate the market
`E.
`.
`.1. Hence it
`is
`the combination of attempting to nullify quality
`differences between the pioneering and late entrant brands and
`introduction of price competition that results in the Iate entrants capturing
`market share’.
`
`Pharmaceuticai markets are subdivided into therapeutic classes. Foliow—
`ing most of the recent economic iiterature on pharmaceuticals (e.g., Stern
`[19959, I regard a therapeutic class as having several sub—markets. I define
`a therapeutic market as a 4-digit ATC code (for example, A028 contains
`all the anti-nicer drugs), and a sub-market as a specified molecule {for
`example,
`raniridme). The ATC code is an international classification
`scheme which classifies drugs by target part of the anatomy, mechanism of
`action, and chemical and therapeutic characteristics. This is a natural
`definition of demand because a 4~digit ATC code inciudes all the moiecuies
`which can theoretically be prescribed for a certain diagnosis. The
`moiecuies themselves differ according to side effects,
`interactions with
`other drugs, specific indications and prices. In the markets I study, a
`physician typicaiiy decides the appropriate molecule for the diagnosis and
`then she decides which trade—name1 version of the molecule to prescribe to
`the patient.
`My work focuses on a particular therapeutic market: anti—ulcer drugs
`(AOZB).
`I analyze this market because it accounts for a considerable
`proportion of worldwide expenditure on pharinaceuticais (around 5%,
`IMS International [1996]). Ulcers also required repeated treatment in the
`early 19905,2 a key feature of my analysis.
`I analyze six molecule
`submarkets (famotidme, ranitz‘dine, nizatidine, roxntidine, omeprazole and
`misoprosrole), which represent more than 90% of the prescriptions during
`the sample period (1990-1992). I restrict my sample to these six molecules
`because the other molecules represent more ‘mature’ and smaiier sub-
`markets, where some of the prices for identical brands differ.3 in each sub—
`market there is a patent-holder and licensees marketing the molecule.
`Much of the literature on trade—name drugs versus generics is concerned
`with the dimensions
`(among others,
`‘perceived quality’ or name
`recognition) according to which these products ‘ditier’. in my analysis I
`focus on competing drugs based on the same active ingredient and
`
`lAll the drugs sold under a license or a patent in the Italian market have a trade name.
`2It has recently been found that approximateiy 80% of peptic ulcers can be cured by
`eradicating Helicobapter Pylori, a bacterium responsible for the recurrence of ulcers, by using
`a combination of antibiotics and antiwulcer drugs (Graham {1993;}.
`3Producers of older molecules had their prices equalized only upon applying for a price
`revision, which happened much later. Moreover, some of the producers in these excluded sub-
`markets are very small firms for whom the assumption of identical quality might not hold.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd, 2000.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 4
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 4
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`rasranancas as THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`
`353
`
`marketed by important producers entering the market at
`-
`4
`time.
`
`the same
`
`If].
`
`THE DATA
`
`The main dataset (provided by the Istz'tato Superiore delta Smite ’) records,
`for a 10% sample of the population of the Metropolitan Area of Rome
`aged 15-65, all
`the prescriptions in the anti-ulcer (A028) drug market
`during the period 19904992. The sample is stratified according to age and
`gender; so that the results are representative of the Rome population.
`This patient-level dataset contains over 310,000 observations. An obser—
`vation records the identity of the prescribing doctor, the identity of the
`patient, the year and month, and the particular presentation form of the
`drug prescribed (for example,
`1 package of ZANTAC 20 tablets, 150 mg
`each). An observation indicates exactly the drug bought by the patient,
`because the records are collected from pharmacies. In the patient—level
`dataset there are more than 3,400 doctors prescribing at least once to one
`of the in—sample patients. A supplementary dataset from the same source
`records all the prescriptions that 350 of these doctors wrote for any of
`their patients during the same period. The supplementary doctor~based
`dataset contains over 7i0,000 prescriptions and each observation records
`exactiy the same information as the patient—level dataset. The final dataset
`used in my estimations has more than 75,000 observations; it retains aii
`the observations in the patientnlevel dataset for the patients who received
`at
`least one prescription from one of the 350 doctors whose entire
`prescription history is known.
`
`Italian Market Three important characteristics of the Italian pharmav
`centical industry are: (i) there is no price and third—party payer variation,
`(ii) the over-thocounter (OTC) market was tiny in the period of interest,
`and direct advertising to patients for prescription drugs had not yet
`started,5 and (iii) during the sample period, the pharmacist had no powor
`to subztitute generics for trade-name drugs, as he does in many American
`states.
`
`Doctors' Prescribing Behavior DOctors heavily prescribe across brands:
`
`“By doing this I believe I have efl‘ectively controlled for all ‘objective’ dimensions of
`difi'erentiation between drugs; therefore I can proceed with my tests of doctor or patient
`indifference fairly confident
`that
`I have controlied for a large share of drug-specific
`heterogeneity.
`5 It is currently illegal throughout the EU and wiii remain so for several years even though
`the subject is now occasionaliy raised.
`5 Helicrstein‘s dataset, therefore, potentiality contains a large amount of measurement error
`in the prescription variable for states where substitution with generics is mandatory.
`© Biackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 5
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 5
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`354
`
`ANDREA COSCELL]
`
`for example, 98.6% of the iii-sample doctors prescribed each of the three
`available brands of omeprazole at least once during the sample period.
`Moreover, doctors usuaily prescribe multiple brands of each molecule in a
`given month. Thus doctors do not specialize in particular drugs over time
`or at a particular point in time.
`Patients are not limited to a singie brand either. At a given point, 40%
`of them will have had experienced a shift to a new brand of the same
`molecule. Different doctors treat the same patient difierentiy. Although
`the proportion of switches in the overall
`sample is 4.5%, among
`observations where patients change doctors, the proportion rises to 9%.
`This latter incidence, however, is much lower than the 48% switch rate that
`we wouid expect were the new doctor not to take into account the patient’s
`history of prescriptions, and to prescribe to the patient according to the
`same proportion used for her other patients.
`Most strikingiy, of those patients who were switched by the new doctor
`and then returned to their original doctor, 50% (44/ 88) are switched again
`when they go back to their usual doctor, and almost all of those (93.2%
`or 4i out of 44) go back to the treatment they received in the previous
`period. These patterns demonstrate clearly that the probability of receiving
`a new treatment is significantly influenced by the doctor’s identity, and
`that doctors differ in their choice among therapeutically equivalent drugs
`for the same patient. Next, I present a formal econometric model which
`accommodates alt these aspects of behavionr.
`
`1V.
`
`EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
`
`iV(i). Theory
`
`I analyze the problem facing a doctor trying to choose among brands of
`a certain molecule. The entire analysis is conditional on the choice of the
`molecule, which is driven by a more complicated set of factors (indications,
`patient’s general health, side effects, price, etc); most of these factors are
`unobservable to the econometrician. By restricting myself to the analysis
`of ‘homogeneous’ goods, I can hold price and quality constant and focus
`on other factors driving the choice of competing brands.7
`The central focus of the study is the question of what brand of a given
`molecule doctor i prescribes to a patient j given this patient’s past
`prescription experience with this molecule. In particular, doctor i must
`decide whether to prescribe the brand the patient received in the previous
`period (hereafter o for ‘oid’ brand) or a new brand, which might generate
`
`7 i do not analyze whether the doctor prescribed a different presentation form, becaese all
`the prodacers sell the same presentation forms, and there was therefore no need to change
`vendor if the doctor or the patient wanted a different presentation form.
`it? Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 6
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 6
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PREFERENCES IN THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`
`355
`
`‘new’ brand). More
`(hereafter n for
`a higher utility to the doctor
`specifiCally, a choice problem where the decision maker decides either to
`stay on the diagonal of a transition probabilities model, or to move off-
`diagonal to any other brand, is collapsed into a simpier problem where the
`decision-maker is confronted with the binary choice of either to stay on
`the diagonal or to move off-diagonal. Since the analysis is conditional on
`the choice of the molecule, ‘new brand” does not inciude other molecules.
`
`IV(ii). Estimation Strategy
`
`The empirical model parameterizes the probability of switching brands as
`a function of patient and doctor attributes. I define as an ‘old’ brand, a, at
`time t, the brand consumed by the patient at time t~— 1. This means that
`1 define as a ‘new’ brand, any brand that differs from the ‘old’ one without
`taking into account whether the ‘new’ brand was previousiy prescribed.
`This means that my analysis focuses on ‘firsnorder’ state dependence, so
`that only one—period lags have an effect. Moreover, since only the year and
`month of the prescription are observed, there are ‘ties’ in the dataset. That
`is, there are patients who receive more than one prescription in a month.
`When the prescriptions are ranked in a chronoiogical order,
`the pre-
`scriptions where the patient, molecule and month are the same are
`randomiy ordered. Finally, the prescriptions in the sampie are written
`either for one package or for two packages of the same brand. The sample
`is evenly split between these two occurrences. Since I model a prescription
`episode, and not quantity, as my dependent variable, I do not distinguish
`between a prescription of two packages and a prescription of one
`package.8
`1 use probit specifications to test the nuli hypothesis of no doctor and/or
`patient preferences. These models include doctors’
`fixed effects and
`patients’ random effects to capture the unobserved (to the econometrician)
`component of doctors’ and patients’ preferences.
`The dataset suffers from the problem of initiai conditions common to
`most dynamic panel data models.
`I observe a sampie of doctors and
`patients for three years, but
`I do not have any information on their
`behavior before the sampie period begins. Ideaity, I would observe the
`doctors’ behavior
`since
`they started practicing and the patients’
`prescriptions since they were first
`treated for nicer problems. This is
`impossible;
`therefore foilowing one of the suggestions put forth in the
`literature (Heckman [1981]),
`i assume that the prescription process starts
`anew if patients have not had a prescription for six months. Thus, I only
`
`3This implies a two-package prescription leads to the same degree of state-dependence as
`a one-package prescription.
`© Blackwell Pubiishers Ltd. 2000,
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 7
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 7
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`356
`
`ANDREA coscsLtI
`
`use data on patients where I am abte to observe whether for six months
`prior they did or did not receive nicer medications. This basicaliy means
`that when the process restarts,
`the decision makers do not retain the
`information on anything which happened before.9
`
`IV(iii). Defieirion of the Variables
`
`Tables I and 11 list all the variables used in the estimations. SWITCH is
`the dependent variable and it takes vaiue 1 if patient j receives a brand at
`time t different from what he received at time t —_
`i (for the same molecule),
`it is 0 otherwise. We review those variabies that are not self~expianatory.
`
`Patients’ Variables
`Timeuinvariam #PRESCRIPTIONS distinguishes among patients ac»
`cording to the seriousness of their nicer problem (e.g., chronic versus
`
`Taste 1
`PAHENTwLEVEL VARanEs USED IN THE ESTIMATION
`
`Dependent variable
`SWITCH
`
`Patients variables
`GENDER
`AGE
`
`#PRESCRIPTIONS
`
`#DOCTORS
`
`#MOLECULES
`
`#SPELL—MOLECULE
`#PAST SWITCH ES
`#MONTHS
`
`Takes value 2 if the brand prescribed is difi‘erent from the
`brand previously prescribed, 0 otherwise
`
`Takes value 1 if female and 2 if maie
`
`Patient’s age
`Total number of prescriptions that the patient receives in
`the sample
`Total number of different physicians who prescribed at
`least one drag to the patient
`'i‘otal number of different molecules that the patient
`consumes in the sampie
`Number of prescriptions of the molecule up to time:
`Number of (within~mo§ecuie} switches up to time t
`Actuai number of months elapsed between the prescription
`at time t and the one at t —— l
`
`NEWDOCTORMTEMP
`
`NEWDOCTOR—PERM
`
`Dummy equal to 1 if the physician is a temporary one For
`the patient, 0 otherwise
`Dummy equal to i if the physician is a new permanent one
`for the patient, 0 otherwise
`NEWDOCTOR—RBT
`Dummy equal to 1 if the patient returns to a previous _
`physician, 0 otherwise
`
`9Most of the models were rerun with a Bumonth window instead. The results are not
`qualitatively difierent.
`© Biackwcl} Piibiishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 8
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 8
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`PREFERENCES IN THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`TABLE II
`DOCTOR-LEVEL VARIABLES osso EN THE ESTIMATEON
`
`357
`
`Doctors' characterisri'cs—ami-ut‘cer market
`QUANTETY
`Average monthly quantity prescribed by the doctor in the entire
`market in the previous six months
`Average monthly hcrfindahl index across intends in the entire
`market in the previous six months
`Average monthly herfindahl index at the molecuie tevel in the
`entire market in the previous six months
`
`HERFBRAND
`
`HERFMOLE
`
`Doctors ’ characterisrics»moiecuie-specrfic
`MOLESHARE
`Share of prescriptions of the molecule by the doctor in the
`previous month
`Weighted proportion of the prescriptions of the molecule mitten
`for the old brand in the 2 previous months (East month’s share
`plus 0.9 of the previous month's share)
`
`% OLD BRAND
`
`occasional), white #MOLBCULES diflercntiatcs patients according to
`their wiilingness to change treatment. #DOCTORS controls for patient"
`specific preferences for changing doctor. Patients who change doctors
`more often probably gather more information on possible treatments;
`therefore it ought to be more difficult for a doctor to switch them; on the
`other hand, these patients might be more experimental.
`
`Time-varying There are three time—varying covariates for the patient,
`which are crucial to measure patient ‘habit’.
`#SPELL~MOLECULE increases over time with any prescription of
`the molecule. #PAST SWITCHES increases only upon a withiremolecuie
`switch. These two ad~hoc variabies proxy for the switching tendency of
`a patient. For example, a patient who receives the tenth prescription of
`the molecule ranilidine, has #SPELL—MOLECULE: 10,
`if #PAST
`SWITCHES m0, this indicates that the patient has always been with the
`same brand. Finally, #MONTHS counts the actuai number of months
`elapsed between prescription episodes.
`it cannot exceed six, given the
`definition of a treatment episode. Finaiiy. there is a series of prescription—
`specyic dummies defining whether the patient is receiving the prescription
`from a substituting physician (NEWDOCTOR«TEMP),1° has permanently
`moved to a new physician (NEWDOCTOR-PERM), or is returning to
`the usual physician (NBWDOCTOR—RBT) after receiving a prescription
`from a substitute. These variables expiore whether doctors have different
`preferences for vendors of a particular molecule. If prescriptions decisions
`
`‘0 Most of the temporary substitutions occur when the physician is on vacation, or the
`patient is out of town when he needs a prescription.
`© Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000,
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 9
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 9
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`358
`
`ANDREA COSCELLi
`
`are determined solely by the patient’s condition, a change in the pre—
`scribing doctor should not vary the patient’s likelihood of being switched.
`
`I use doctor covariates which are time-varying. Most
`Doctors’ Variables
`of them summarize the prescribing behavior of the physicians in the six
`months immediately prior to the prescription episode.
`
`Constant across molecale markets Tabte 11 describes the variables in
`detail. QUANTITY distinguishes between heavy and light prescribers of
`anti—ulcer drugs, and proxies for the size of the doctor’s patient baSe.
`HERFBRAND proxies for the doctors’ preference to prescribe multiple
`brands, whiie HERFMOLE controis for the dispersion in prescribing
`behavior of the doctor due to choice of diflerent molecules, which is
`dictated by heterogeneity in the patients’ pool. Its coefficient does not have
`any specific economic meaning:
`it simpiy allows me to interpret
`the
`coefficient on HERFBRAND as
`representing doctors’ preference for
`prescribing multiple brands, rather than their need to prescribe multiple
`drugs (molecules) due to therapeutic considerations. This distinction is
`based on the assumption that the doctor first chooses the molecule that
`suits the patient and then decides which brand to prescribe.
`
`Molecule-specific % OLD BRAND captures habit persistence by the
`doctor. MOLESHARE proxies for the importance that the molecule has
`for the doctor.
`
`Molecafe markets The number of competing products, the time since
`the moiecute entered the market, the size of the vendors, and the amount
`of advertising ail differ across molecule markets. I use molecule dummies
`to proxy for the difi‘erent competitive conditions in each molecnie market.
`Finally,
`I
`include monthiy dummies to controt for exogenous changes
`(such as reguiatory changes) that occur during the sample period.
`
`Summary Statistics Table III provides sampie summary statistics. There
`are slightiy more than 75,000 observations in the original sample, an
`observation being a prescription.
`I exciude the following observations:
`(i) patients who received prescriptions from doctors whose entire pre-
`scription history is not known, (ii) the first prescription of each meteorite
`for each patient, so as to initialize the process, and (iii) all prescriptions in
`the first 6 months and those more than 6 months apart for the same patient
`because of the initial conditions problem discussed above. This leaves
`43,840 observations.
`There are more than 5,000 different patients and 350 doctors in the
`sample. I observe a change of brand (SWITCH) in 4% of the observations.
`There are slightly more prescriptions written to females in the sample,
`63 Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 10
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014—00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 10
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`sssrenencns IN THE PRESCRIPTION DECISION
`TABLE III
`SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR THE SAME’LEW
`
`359
`
`Max
`Std. Dev. Min
`Mean
`
`
`Dependent variable
`Switch
`
`Patient 's variables
`Gender: i if female, 2 if male
`Age
`#In-sample prescriptions
`#Molecules prescribed in~sample
`#Diiferent doctors prescribing
`#Prescréptions of the molecule
`#Past switches up to time t
`#Months between prescriptions
`New doctor—temp
`New doctorwperm
`New doctorwret
`
`0.040
`
`0. t9?
`
`0
`
`1
`
`'
`
`1.484
`62.73
`29.478
`LS7
`1.629
`14.955
`0.396
`1.232
`0.018
`0.021
`0.024
`
`0.499
`12.65
`19.75
`$.09
`1.1 l
`12.68
`1.205
`1.277
`0.134
`0.143
`0.155
`
`l—F
`:5
`2
`l
`l
`2
`0
`0
`0
`0
`0
`
`ZWM
`85
`S26
`8
`14
`106
`E8
`6
`1
`1
`1
`
`Doctors’ skaracteristicsmanti»ulcer market
`Average monthly quantity prescribed in~sample
`Hcrfindahl brand level
`Herfindaiii molecule level
`
`Doctors ' characteristics-moiecule specific
`% Old brand prescribed
`Motecule share
`
`876.168
`0.243
`0.485
`
`297.568
`0.069
`0.113
`
`107.08
`0.09
`0.192
`
`2512.717
`0.68
`0.93
`
`0.97
`0.52%
`
`0.405
`0.256
`
`0.025
`0.025
`
`1.9
`1
`
`Molecuie sub-marker
`E
`0
`0.438
`0.742
`ranidine
`t
`0
`0.199
`0.04
`nizatr'a’z'ne
`1
`0
`0.09!
`0.008
`roxatidine
`
`omeprazoie 1 0.097 0.297 0
`
`
`
`
`whiic the average age is around 62. Turning to the time-varying covariates
`for the patients: the average prescription is written to a patient who is
`purchasing the particuiar motecule for the fourteenth time (#Si’ELLw
`MOLECULE) and who has already switched brands 0.4 times ($75“ PAST
`SWITCHES). The average time betWeen two prescriptions (#MONTHS)
`is less than two months. Finally, in approximately 6% of the prescriptions,
`the prescribing doctor differs from the one who wrote the previous
`prescription. The number of prescriptions where the patient temporariiy
`visits a doctor different
`from the one responsible for
`the previous
`prescription (NEWDOCTOR-TEMP) is about 1.8%; whereas 2% of the
`prescriptions are written by a new doctor, who then becomes the usual
`doctor for the patient (NEWDOCTOR—PERM). Finatiy, 2.4% of the
`prescriptions are written by the usual physician after the patient has been
`prescribed something by a substitute in the previous period.
`The unit of measurement for the quantity variable (QUANTITY) is
`the defined daily dose, which is an international measurement unit. For
`© Biaekweli Publishers Ltd. 2000.
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249. pg. 11
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`|PR2014-00676
`
`IMMUNOGEN 2249, pg. 11
`Phigenix v. Immunogen
`IPR2014-00676
`
`

`

`360
`
`ANDREA COSCBLLI
`
`each molecule, the daily number of milligrams of the chemical compound
`that the average patient needs is defined. Therefore any package can be
`transformed into a number of days of therapy for the average patient.
`Finally, the dummy variables for the molecule markets indicate that 74%
`of the prescriptions in the sample were for mnitidine,
`followed by
`omepmzole with 9%.
`Table IV compares the market shares in the original sample to those in
`the estimation samples. First, column (1) shows that within-molecule
`market shares differ. Second, the main estimation sample is remarkably
`similar to the original sample, while the switching sample in column (3)
`
`TABLE IV
`MARKET SHARES IN THE SAMPLE
`
`Column (1) shows market shares in the overall sample; in column (2) market shares in the
`sample used in the estimation are reported. Column (3) is a subset of the sample used in
`column (2), conditional on the patients’ being prescribed a new brand. Column (4) indicates
`the expected brand frequency in the switch sample based on the total in-sample market shares
`Estimation
`Overall
`Estimation
`sample and
`Conditional
`
`sample
`sample
`switch
`probabilities
`
`Famotidl‘ne
`FAMODIL
`GASTRIDIN
`MOTIAX
`
`Ranitidz'ne
`RANInEN
`Rammoc
`RANinIL
`TRIGGER
`Uncax
`ULKOBRIN
`ZANTAC
`
`Nizatidine
`CRONIZAT
`Ntzax
`ZANEZAL
`
`Roxatidz‘ne
`GASTRALGIN
`NBOHZ
`ROXIT
`
`0.467
`0.448
`0.083
`
`0,02
`0.021
`0.419
`0.021
`0.029
`0.002
`0.483
`
`0.359
`0.581
`0.059
`
`0.332
`0.199
`0.468
`
`0.458
`0.453
`0.088
`
`0.03
`0.025
`0.432
`0.024
`0.024
`0.003
`0.467
`
`0.3

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket