throbber
This PDF is a selection from a published volume
`from the National Bureau of Economic Research
`
`Volume Title: Frontiers in Health Policy Research,
`Volume 6
`
`Volume Author/Editor: David M. Cutler and Alan
`M. Garber, editors
`
`Volume Publisher: MIT Press
`
`Volume ISBN: 0-262-03309-7
`
`Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/cutl03-1
`
`Conference Date: May 29, 2002
`
`Publication Date: January 2003
`
`Title: Demand Effects of Recent Changes in Prescription
`Drug Promotion
`
`Author: Meredith B. Rosenthal, Ernst R. Berndt,
`Julie M. Donohue, Arnold M. Epstein, Richard G.
`Frank
`
`URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c9862
`
`

`
`1 D
`
`emand Effects of Recent Changes in
`Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`Meredith B. Rosenthal, Harvard School of Public Health
`Ernst R. Berndt, Massachusetts Institute of Technology and NBER
`Julie M. Donohue, Harvard Medical School
`Arnold M. Epstein, Harvard School of Public Health
`Richard G. Frank, Harvard Medical School and NBER
`
`Executive Summary
`
`The release of clarified Food and Drug Administration (FDA) guide-
`lines and independent changes in consumer behavior provide an
`opportunity to study the effects of direct-to-consumer advertising
`(DTCA) in the prescription drug market alongside the effects of various
`physician-oriented promotions. We examine the effects of DTCA and
`detailing for brands in five therapeutic classes of drugs, using monthly
`aggregate U.S. data from August 1996 through December 1999. In
`terms of impact of DTCA on demand, we provide evidence on two
`issues: (1) do increases in DTCA increase the market size of an entire
`therapeutic class? and (2) does DTCA increase within-class market
`share of advertised drugs? Our findings suggest that, for these classes
`of drugs, DTCA has been effective primarily through increasing the
`size of the entire class. Overall, we estimate that 13 to 22 percent of
`the recent growth in prescription drug spending is attributable to the
`effects of DTCA.
`
`Advertisements contain the only truth to be relied on in a newspaper.
`
`Thomas Jefferson1
`
`Advertising is a racket . . . its constructive contribution to humanity is exactly minus
`zero.
`
`F. Scott Fitzgerald1
`
`I think I was wrong. . . . On the whole, I think there is a lot of educational benefit [to
`direct to consumer prescription drug advertising].
`David A. Kessler, M.D., former FDA Commissioner2
`
`

`
`2
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`Since 1994, total spending on consumer-directed promotion for pre-
`scription drugs has grown nearly tenfold (Henry J. Kaiser Family Foun-
`dation 2000). Consumers and their physicians report that prescription
`drug advertisements are increasingly influential. In surveys of consum-
`ers, the share of people reporting that they have seen an advertisement
`on television or heard an advertisement on the radio for a prescription
`drug more than doubled between 1993 and 2000, reaching 81 percent
`by 2002 (Alperstein and Peyrot 1993, Newshour with Jim Lehrer/
`Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation / Harvard School of Public Health
`2000, Aikin 2002). Some estimates indicate that as many as 25 percent
`of Americans have asked their doctors about a medication as a result of
`seeing an advertisement (Prevention Magazine 2001). Similarly, many
`physicians report that their patients have asked them about drugs as
`a direct consequence of consumer advertising (Borzo 1997, Kaufman-
`Sherr and Hoffman 1997).
`The rise of direct-to-consumer advertising (DTCA) of prescription
`drugs represents a departure from the industry's historical concentra-
`tion on promotion to physicians, hospitals, and other health care orga-
`nizations.3 This phenomenon is highly targeted toward a minority of
`products. In one recent study of 391 major branded drugs in 1999, only
`18 percent had positive DTCA expenditures, whereas 95 percent of
`brands sent "detailers" to visit physicians' offices (Neslin 2001). Tradi-
`tional physician-oriented forms of promotion remain important. Even
`among those products that employ DTCA, professional promotion
`continues to command a larger share of marketing budgets (table 1.1).
`The change in marketing mix by pharmaceutical manufacturers is
`likely a response to recent changes in market and regulatory condi-
`tions.4 Consumers are increasingly seeking active participation in their
`own health care, aided in part by the wealth of information available
`on the Internet. At the same time, physicians may have less discretion
`over choice of brand-name drugs than they once did as a result of direct
`and indirect constraints placed on their prescribing behavior by man-
`aged care. In addition, in 1997, the FDA released explicit tentative
`guidelines (finalized in 1999) regarding advertising to consumers via
`electronic media that may have facilitated more widespread use of this
`promotional strategy. In particular, the new FDA guidelines clarified
`the requirements for adequate disclosure of information concerning in-
`dications, and risks and effects of a drug, thus removing a major barrier
`to television and radio advertising (Rosenthal et al. 2002).
`
`

`
`Effects of Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`The release of clarified FDA guidelines and independent changes in
`consumer behavior provide an opportunity to study the effects of
`DTCA in the prescription drug market as well as the effects of various
`physician-oriented promotions. In this paper, we examine the effects
`of two types of promotional spending for brands in five therapeutic
`classes of drugs, and we use monthly aggregate U.S. data from August
`1996 through December 1999. Specifically, we provide evidence on two
`issues: (1) do increases in DTCA increase the market size of an entire
`therapeutic class? and (2) does relative DTCA within a given therapeu-
`tic class affect market shares within that therapeutic class? In both
`cases, we examine the effects relative to traditional physician-oriented
`promotional efforts.
`
`I. Review of Related Literature
`
`Our research builds on and relates to several other studies. Early eco-
`nomic studies of physician-oriented marketing of prescription drugs
`by Bond and Lean (1977), Hurwitz and Caves (1988), Leffler (1981),
`and Vernon (1981) considered evidence regarding whether this market-
`ing was more "persuasive" than "informative," although the distinc-
`tion between the two was ambiguous. This distinction reflects an
`earlier, more general literature that viewed advertising alternatively as
`changing consumers' preferences (Kaldor 1950), creating or exaggerat-
`ing product differentiation and thereby increasing barriers to entry
`(Bain 1956), or providing information about a product's characteristics
`and its price (Stigler 1961). A common finding from the empirical litera-
`ture was that professional promotion of prescription drugs increased
`entry costs and decreased price competition by increasing perceived
`product differentiation. A related medical study on physician detailing
`by Avorn, Chen and Hartley (1982) advocated that counterdetailing be
`utilized to offset the unbalanced information provided by prescription
`drug detailers.5
`More recent research by King (2000) on anti-ulcer medications finds
`that a brand's own marketing reduces (in absolute value) a brand's
`own price-elasticities of demand, but that total industry marketing
`(i.e. the sum of marketing expenditures for each brand in the class) re-
`duces the extent of product differentiation. Berndt et al. (1997) dis-
`tinguish between "industry expanding" and "rivalrous" marketing
`efforts, and find that, for anti-ulcer medications, both medical journal
`
`

`
`41
`
`.ft
`
`0.00
`0.03
`0.01
`0.05
`0.00
`
`0.06
`0.15
`0.11
`0.00
`0.00
`
`0.02
`0.00
`0.00
`
`0.01
`0.00
`0.01
`0.00
`0.01
`0.00
`
`0.02
`0.11
`0.12
`0.13
`0.18
`
`0.08
`0.30
`0.26
`0.44
`0.68
`
`0.08
`0.15
`2.05
`
`0.09
`0.14
`0.16
`0.21
`0.35
`0.52
`
`0.02
`0.07
`0.07
`0.07
`0.07
`
`0.04
`0.17
`0.09
`0.18
`0.19
`
`0.06
`0.10
`0.84
`
`0.06
`0.10
`0.10
`0.09
`0.15
`0.21
`
`0.00
`0.04
`0.05
`0.06
`0.11
`
`0.04
`0.14
`0.17
`0.26
`0.49
`
`0.02
`0.05
`1.21
`
`0.03
`0.05
`0.05
`0.12
`0.21
`0.31
`
`1991
`1991
`1996
`1991
`1993
`
`1993
`1995
`1996
`1994
`1996
`
`1989
`1995
`1999
`
`1987
`1991
`1992
`1993
`1994
`1998
`
`ratio
`to sales
`3-year DTC
`
`ratio'
`to sales
`promotion
`physician
`Total
`
`sales ratio
`sampling to
`3-year
`
`sales ratio
`detailing to
`3-year
`
`date
`approval
`FDA
`
`Merck
`Merck
`Pfizer
`Bristol Myers Squibb
`Novartis
`
`Schering Plough
`Pfizer
`Aventis
`Celltech Pharms
`Wallace
`
`Astrazeneca
`Tap Pharm
`Eisai
`
`Eli Lilly
`Pfizer
`GlaxoSmithKline
`Wyeth Ayerst
`Bristol Myers Squibb
`Forest Labs
`
`Manufacturer
`
`Mevacor
`Zocor
`Lipitor
`Pravachol
`Lescol
`Cholesterol
`Claritin
`Zyrtec
`Allegra
`Semprex-D
`Astelin
`Antihistamines
`Priosec
`Prevacid
`Aciphex
`PPIs
`Prozac
`Zoloft
`Paxil
`Effexor XR
`Serzone
`Celexa
`Antidepressants
`
`Manufacturer, approval date, and promotion to sales ratios for five therapeutic classes, 1997-1999
`Table 1.1
`
`

`
`01
`
`0.00
`0.00
`0.12
`0.09
`0.00
`0.23
`
`0.00
`0.40
`0.20
`0.47
`0.32
`0.48
`
`'Total physician promotion includes detailing and retail value of free samples. It does not includejournal advertising.
`from the Food and Drug Administration's Orange Book.
`data from IMS Health, 2001; DTCA data from Competitive Media Reporting, Strategy Report, 2001; manufacturerand FDA approval date obtained
`Sources: Detailing data from Scott-Levin Personal Selling Audit, 2001; sales data from Scott-Levin, SourcePrescription Audit, 2001; sampling
`Beconase
`Vancenase
`Flonase
`Nasacort
`IThinocort
`Nasonex
`Nasal Sprays
`
`GlaxoSmithKline
`Schering Plough
`GlaxoSmithKline
`Aventis
`Astrazeneca
`Schering Plough
`
`0.00
`0.37
`0.14
`0.37
`0.20
`0.26
`
`0.00
`0.03
`0.06
`0.11
`0.12
`0.22
`
`Prior to 1982
`Prior to 1982
`1994
`1991
`1994
`1997
`
`

`
`6
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`and physician detailing marketing stocks positively affect own-brand
`sales. They also report that the impact of total class marketing efforts
`on total class sales is positive, and generally (but not always) declines
`with the number of products on the market. Rizzo (1999) reports that
`for antthypertensive drugs, both stocks and flows of detailing expendi-
`tures decrease the price elasticity through the development of greater
`brand loyalty.
`Using a proprietary data set from a pharmaceutical manufacturer
`that incorporates physician-specific marketing measures for one of its
`brands, Manchanda, Chintagunta and Gertzis (2000) find that detailing
`has a significant positive impact on the number of prescriptions written
`for that drug by the physician; that this marginal impact increases
`when free product samples are also provided to the physician; and that,
`for the majority of physicians in their sample, diminishing (though still
`positive) returns to detailing had already set in. Gonul et al. (2001)
`report similar diminishing returns to physician detailing, but find that
`detailing and free samples increase price sensitivity, where price is
`measured as the average retail price for the drug.
`The empirical studies cited above focused on physician detailing and
`in some cases on medical journal advertising, but did not examine
`DTCA.6 Unlike physician-oriented promotions, to the extent DTCA
`might raise awareness among previously untreated consumers of the
`existence of potentially effective treatments, DTCA could bring more
`patients into physician offices. Whether the effect of such increased
`"physician office foot traffic" is greater on overall therapeutic class
`sales, or on the share of sales for the specific brand named in the adver-
`tisement, is unclear a priori and is an empirical question addressed in
`this study.
`Prior to 1997, DTCA was permitted if a medical condition was men-
`tioned but the brand was not; or if the brand was mentioned, no men-
`tion was made of the medical condition for which it was intended, and
`instead the ad encouraged the individual to see her or his physician
`regarding the brand. Berndt et al. (1995) obtained advertising agency
`DTCA data for branded anti-ulcer (H2-antagonist) prescription drugs
`through May 1994, along with detailing and medical journal advertis-
`ing data from other sources. For the entire IJ2 therapeutic class, adver-
`tising demand elasticities were 0.55 for detailing, 0.20 for medical
`journal advertising, and 0.01 for this type of DTCA; the sum of these
`elasticities is 0.76, suggesting decreasing returns to scale for overall
`advertising. Within this therapeutic class, although a brand's own de-
`
`

`
`Effects of Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`7
`
`tailing and medical journal advertising stocks positively affected mar-
`ket shares, this was not the case for DTCA.
`Two recent studies of DTCA by Wosinska (2001) and Ling, Berndt,
`and Kyle (2002) incorporate data after the FDA's 1997 clarification
`of DTCA guidelines. Using 1996-1999 prescription drug claims data
`for 4,728 patients who filled a total of 11,529 new prescriptions for
`cholesterol-reducing drugs in the Blue Shield of California medical
`plans, along with national data on physician detailing, samples, and
`DTCA, Wosinska finds that DTCA positively affects total therapeutic
`class sales, but affects an individual brand positively only if that brand
`has a preferred status on the third-party payer's formulary
`Unlike the cholesterol-reducing drugs, the H2-antagonist drugs are
`sold in prescription (Rx) form and, since 1995-1996, also as over-the-
`counter (OTC) drugs. Both OTC and Rx versions of these brands have
`utilized DTCA, and thus various spillovers between Rx and OTC
`DTCA can be assessed, both between and within brands. Ling, Berndt,
`and Kyle find that DTCA marketing of OTC brands has no spillover
`to the same brand in the Rx market. Within the Rx market, own-brand
`physician-oriented detailing and medical journal advertising efforts
`have positive and long-lived effects on own Rx market share, while
`DTCA of the Rx brand has no significant impact on own Rx market
`share. Within the OTC market, not only are own-brand effects of DTCA
`on the OTC brand significantly positive and long-lived, but physician-
`oriented Rx marketing efforts have positive own-brand spillovers to
`the OTC share. DTCA efforts for Rx brands have no significant impact
`on same-brand OTC shares.
`
`II. Theoretical Considerations
`
`The codfish lays ten thousand eggs,
`The homely hen lays one.
`The codfish never cackles
`To tell you what she's done.
`And so we scorn the codfish,
`While the humble hen we prize,
`Which only goes to show you
`That it pays to advertise.1
`The theoretical foundations underlying the economics of advertis-
`ing rely in large part on Dorfman and Steiner (1954), who showed
`that for a profit-maximizing monopolist facing a downward-sloping
`
`

`
`8
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`linear demand curve, the optimal advertising expenditure to dollar
`sales ratio equaled the ratio of two elasticities: EQAthe elasticity of
`quantity demanded with respect to advertising efforts, and £QAthe
`elasticity of quantity demanded with respect to price (in absolute
`value). The equation for this relationship is shown below:
`
`Advertising dollars
`Sales dollars
`
`QA
`
`EQP
`
`(1 1
`
`The Dorfman-Steirier theorem is static because it assumes that adver-
`tising efforts last only one time period, but it can be generalized readily
`to a dynamic case in which the effects of advertising efforts persist
`several periods into the futurethe so-called carryover effects (Schma-
`lensee 1972). When there are several marketing instruments (and con-
`stant unit marketing media costs), under reasonable conditions the
`optimal ratio of expenditures for any two media equals the ratio of
`their marketing elasticities (Palda 1969).
`In terms of demand marketing elasticities and advertising-sales ra-
`tios, it is useful to consider the taxonomy of Nelson (1970, 1974), who
`has distinguished search and experience goods as polar opposites. If
`a consumer can determine a product's quality and impact prior to pur-
`chase merely by visual, tactile, or analytical inspection, the product
`is said to have search qualities. Examples of search goods are many
`electronic goods, tools, and credit cards. If a customer must consume
`the product to predict its quality and impact, the good is said to have
`experience qualities. Examples of experience goods include cosmetics,
`restaurants, and cereals. In practice precise demarcation of goods into
`search versus experience is not possible, particularly when multi-
`attribute goods have both search and experience qualities. In general,
`however, goods with dominant experience attributes have greater
`advertising-sales ratios than do goods with dominant search qualities.
`To the extent prescription pharmaceuticals have idiosyncratic and un-
`predictable effects (differential efficacy, side effects, and adverse inter-
`actions with other drugs), pharmaceuticals would appear to have more
`experience than search qualities. For those pharmaceuticals having
`highly predictable outcomes, however, search qualities may dominate.
`Carlton and Perloff (1994) suggest that producers of search goods are
`more likely to use informational advertising, while experience goods
`producers are more likely to use persuasive advertising. They note,
`however, that the division is not perfect, nor is there unanimity in what
`constitutes information versus persuasion. They interpret the greater
`
`

`
`Effects of Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`9
`
`advertising-sales ratios of experience goods as possibly reflecting the
`fact that "images (used in persuasive advertising) are forgotten more
`quickly than facts (used in informative advertising). Thus, consumers
`may learn and remember that a particular good has fewer calories (is
`"less filling") in one or a few exposures to an advertisement, but need
`to be bombarded with repeated exposures to be convinced that a prod-
`uct "tastes great."7
`The effects of advertising on the welfare of individuals have long
`been analyzed and debated. Carlton and Perloff summarize this litera-
`hire by stating that "the welfare effects of advertising are complex and
`depend on the type of product and type of advertising," and therefore
`"are generally ambiguous."8 Brand loyalty, for example, may reduce
`price responsiveness of demand, but can also reduce consumers' search
`costs.9 Bagwell (2001) provides a useful collection of economics articles
`dealing with the theoretical foundations and empirical analyses of ad-
`vertising as information versus persuasion; search versus experience;
`and the relationships among advertising, product quality and market
`structure.'°
`Finally, in addition to affecting demand, advertising can be used as
`a strategic tool to affect possible entry into a product market. Ellison
`and Ellison (2000) hypothesize and empirically assess branded phar-
`maceutical firms' advertising strategies in the context of affecting po-
`tential generic entry as the brand's patent protection expires. Their
`model predicts and they find empirical evidence supporting the notion
`that branded drugs with medium-size markets reduce their advertising
`intensities to a greater extent prior to patent expiration than do drugs
`with either very small or very large markets.
`
`III. The Marketing of Prescription Pharmaceuticals: Descriptive
`Data
`
`Pharmaceutical companies currently employ several promotional strat-
`egies for prescription drugs designed to target physicians and consum-
`ers, respectively (table 1.2). Because physicians have long been the key
`decision makers when it comes to choosing a prescription drug, phar-
`maceutical companies traditionally have concentrated most of their
`marketing efforts on physicians, and still do so today. These physician-
`oriented marketing efforts include visits or phone calls by pharmaceu-
`tical sales representatives to physicians (detailing), free samples, print
`advertising, and sponsorship of medical education events. In 2000, the
`
`

`
`10
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`Table 1.2
`Spending on physician-directed promotion and promotion to sales ratios, 1996-2000
`
`Dollars (thousands)
`
`Detailing
`Journal advertising
`Retail value of samples
`Total physician promotion
`Direct-to-consumer promotion
`Total Promotion
`
`Promotion to sales ratios
`
`1996
`
`3,010
`459
`4,904
`8,373
`791
`9,164
`
`1996
`
`1997
`
`3,365
`510
`6,047
`9,922
`1,069
`10,991
`
`4,057
`498
`6,602
`11,157
`1,317
`12,474
`
`1997
`
`1998
`
`1998
`
`1999
`
`2000
`
`4,803
`484
`7,954
`13,241
`2,467
`15,708
`
`2000
`
`4,320
`470
`7,230
`12,020
`1,848
`13,868
`
`1999
`
`Detailing
`Journal advertising
`Retail value of samples
`Total physician promotion
`Direct-to-consumer promotion
`Total promotion
`
`0.047
`0.046
`0.050
`0.043
`0.043
`0.007
`0.007
`0.006
`0.005
`0.004
`0.084
`0.076
`0.081
`0.071
`0.071
`0.129
`0.138
`0.137
`0.118
`0.118
`0.012
`0.016
`0.015
`0.018
`0.022
`0.141
`0.153
`0.153
`0.136
`0.140
`Sources: Physician promotion spending data are from IMS Health, Integrated Promotional
`ServicesTM, June 2001; sales data are from Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers
`of America, Annual Survey, 2001; direct-to-consumer promotion spending data are from
`IMS Health and Competitive Media Reporting, June 2001.
`
`vast majority of spending on physician-oriented promotion (about 81
`percent) was concentrated on detailing (30.6 percent) and samples
`(50.6 percent).
`Consumer-oriented promotion, which includes advertising in both
`print and electronic media, was nearly nonexistent as an approach to
`promotion of pharmaceuticals in the United States as of 1980. Begin-
`ning in the 1980s and early 1990s, a limited amount of DTCA began
`appearing. By 1994 a rapidly increasing trend in DTCA spending
`became apparent (figure 1.1). The release of the clarified FDA guide-
`lines in 1997 occurred in the midst of this trend and may have accel-
`erated it. By 2000, DTCA comprised 15.7 percent of total promotion
`expenditures.'1
`As shown in table 1.1, there is very substantial heterogeneity in
`DTCA and physician-oriented promotion to sales ratios. For new prod-
`ucts, this ratio can be as high as 2.05 (Aciphex, a proton pump iiihibi-
`tor), and as low as 0.0 (Mevacor, a cholesterol-reducing drug). Within
`classes, there is also substantial heterogeneity in DTCA, detailing, and
`sampling to dollar sales ratios (e.g., the antidepressants and nasal spray
`classes in table 1.1).
`
`

`
`Effects of Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`11
`
`FDA Guidelines Released
`
`1994
`
`1995
`
`1996
`
`1997
`
`Year
`
`1998
`
`1999
`
`2000
`
`3,000
`
`2,500
`
`g 2,000
`
`1,500
`
`1,000
`
`0 Ca
`
`C)
`
`500
`
`0
`
`Figure 1.1
`Trend in direct to consumer advertising spending, 1994-2000
`
`Source: IMS Health and Competitive Media Reporting
`
`IV. Empirical Implementation
`
`Our aim is to estimate the impact of DTCA on consumer demand for
`prescription drugs. The literature on the demand for prescription drugs
`uses several approaches to model specification, including implementa-
`tion of an almost ideal demand system (AIDS), Cobb-Douglas specifi-
`cations, and logit models (Ellison et al. 1997; Rizzo 1999; King 2000;
`Ling, Berndt, and Kyle 2002; Frank and Hartman 2002). Each specifica-
`tion has its advocates in the literature. None has yet been shown to
`be superior in estimating demand models in markets for prescription
`drugs.
`Following others, in the demand analysis pursued here we estimate
`the demand for prescription drug products in the context of multistage
`budgeting. That is, we estimate models of the impact of promotional
`spending (DTCA and detailing) at the level of the entire therapeutic
`class (e.g., selective serotonin reuptake inhibitors [SSRI] antidepres-
`sants) and at the level of the individual product within the class (e.g.,
`Prozac among the SSR[s).'2 This multistage structure is illustrated in
`figure 1.2. At the top level of the tree, which represents the therapeutic
`
`

`
`12
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`Figure 1.2
`Multi-tier demand structure
`
`class of drugs, we estimate the impact of DTCA spending and detailing
`in the context of a Cobb-Douglas demand specification (double loga-
`rithmic). In the analysis of competition at the individual product level
`within each class, we specify and estimate three alternative models:
`(1) an AIDS type specification; (2) a logit model with log of quantity
`share divided by (1 - quantity share) on the left-hand side, and prices
`and promotional spending on the right-hand side; and (3) a Cobb-
`Douglas model in log levels.
`
`Data Sources
`
`We examine monthly data from August 1996 to December 1999 for
`five therapeutic classes of drugs: recent vintage anti-depressants (SSRIs
`plus serotonin/norepinephrine reuptake inhibitors [SNR[s}), antthy-
`perlipidemics, proton pump inhibitors, nasal sprays, and antihista-
`mines (table 1.2). These classes were selected on the basis of the
`following criteria: (1) presence of at least one product with high DTCA
`expenditures during the time period, (2) within-class variation in
`DTCA, and (3) within-class variation in the life cycles of the drugs. The
`classes treat a wide variety of ailments, are indicated for different pa-
`tient populations, and are prescribed by several different clinical spe-
`cialties. Data were collected on all of the drugs in each of these five
`classes.
`Sales and promotion data for the selected products were obtained
`from marketing research firms. Data on DTCA spending were obtained
`
`

`
`Effects of Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`13
`
`from Competitive Media Reporting (formerly known as Leading
`National Advertisers), which tracks local and national advertising
`campaigns in major media, such as television and radio, for brands
`with at least $25,000 in annual advertising expenditures. Three ma-
`jor components of professional promotional spending are reported
`here: detailing to office-based physicians, detailing to hospital-based
`physicians, and the value of free samples left with physicians. Drug-
`specific data on professional journal advertising, which represents a
`small percentage of overall promotional expenditures for products in
`the six drug classes, was not included.
`Spending data on detailing were obtained from Scott-Levin Inc.,
`a pharmaceutical market research firm. Scott-Levin imputes spending
`on detailing from a panel of roughly 12,000 office- and hospital-based
`physicians, which comprises roughly 2-3 percent of the U.S. physician
`population. The physicians track their contacts with pharmaceu-
`tical sales representatives. Data on the retail value of free samples
`provided by pharmaceutical companies were obtained from IMS
`Health, which uses a panel of 1,265 front office staff in medical prac-
`tices to monitor the volume of samples dropped off by sales repre-
`sentatives. Sales data were obtained from Scott-Levin, which audits
`over 35,000 retail pharmacies and projects total sales based on
`an independent estimate of total U.S. retail sales of prescription
`drugs.
`Market shares were constructed from product-level data on sales for
`the drugs in each of the five classes. Price data were constructed by
`Scott-Levin using their sales data. We then created a quantity sold vari-
`able based on dividing sales by price for a particular month. Note that
`this price variable is not the average consumer copayment for that
`drug, but instead is the average price received by wholesalers from
`their customers.
`Patent information was collected from the Food and Drug Adminis-
`tration's Orange Book. A variable was created to indicate the number
`of months left on a product's patent. Order of entry within a class was
`determined based on the FDA approval date available through the
`Orange Book.
`Table 1.2 identifies the therapeutic class and individual product com-
`binations that are analyzed below. Together these five classes ac-
`counted for 30 percent of all DTCA in 1999. Table 1.2 also reports the
`year each drug was approved, the three-year average promotion to
`sales ratio for detailing, sampling, and DTCA.
`
`

`
`14
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`Basic Models
`
`We now set out the basic estimation models used in the analysis. As
`noted above, the Cobb-Douglas formulation is used for both the class
`level demand model as well as the individual product demand model.
`Equation (1.2) is the Cobb-Douglas specification for the product spe-
`cific analyses:
`in q = a +
`
`in DTCA + 2 In Det +
`
`(1.2)
`
`where Det is detailing and the X are other explanatory variables.
`Equation (1.3) represents the general specification of the modified
`AIDS model.
`
`S = a +
`
`In () + in DTCA +
`
`In Det +
`
`(1.3)
`
`where 5, is the dollar revenue share of the ith drug within a therapeutic
`class, and P1 and P1 are prices of drugs i and] (in our model, P1 is actually
`the share-weighted price index for other competitors in the class, since
`there are more than two drugs in every class). Finally, we use the same
`regressors in estimating model specifications where the dependent
`variable is specified as the logit of quantity shares for the individual
`drug products. Several variants of these specifications are also esti-
`mated, as discussed below.
`
`Specification and Measurement of Key Variables
`
`There are two important sets of measurement and specification issues
`with our demand models of prescription drug promotion: (1) the mea-
`surement and specification of the price variables, and (2) the specifica-
`tion of promotional spending. The appropriate price to measure in a
`traditional consumer demand model is the out-of-pocket cost of the
`drug to the consumer. For various reasons, this desired measure is not
`available. The Scott-Levin data we analyze measure price as the pay-
`ment made by drugstores to wholesalers for each drug. Because this
`measure takes into account discounts and charge-backs to pharmaceu-
`tical manufacturers, these prices are not simple list prices. Neverthe-
`less, these observed prices do not account for the rebates given to health
`plans and other third-party payers for prescription drugs, nor the
`structure of beneficiary cost sharing for prescription drugs by health
`
`

`
`Effects of Changes in Prescription Drug Promotion
`
`15
`
`plans. Both the level of rebates obtained by different payers and the
`structure of copayments are quite heterogeneous, even within the cus-
`tomers of a single drugstore (Frank 2001). Thus, the observed prices
`are measured with error and are probably not closely correlated with
`the desired consumer out-of-pocket price. For these reasons, we take
`two approaches in empirical implementation. In one set of models, we
`include the mismeasured price variables. In another set of models, we
`omit the price variables and instead include a more extensive set of
`indicator variables to account for time trends and unobserved cross-
`sectional effects.
`The specification of measures of promotional spending has generally
`taken one of three forms in the literature. Promotion has been treated
`as a simple flow variable that is measured by current levels of promo-
`tional spending (Wosinska 2001). That approach assumes that current
`buying behavior depends largely on current exposure to promotional
`activities. A second approach specifies promotional activity as affecting
`consumer. choice in terms of a lag structure (Rizzo 1999, Wosinska
`2001). The assumption here is that the appropriate measure is still
`viewed as a flow, only there is a lagged response to the promotional
`activities. The third approach is to treat promotional activity as a stock
`that depreciates at a constant rate over time (Berndt et al. 1995, 1997).
`Our point of departure is to treat promotional spending as a simple
`flow. We also explored creating a stock. Our historical data on DTCA
`and detailing is quite limited, however. Therefore, we experimented
`with a variable based on three-month cumulative spending. When we
`used this variable in the specifications, our time series was shortened,
`and the resulting parameter estimates did not differ markedly from
`those assuming a simple flow. Therefore, we chose to focus on the re-
`sults that are based on treating promotional spending as a simple flow.
`We account for the possibility that spending on DTCA and physician
`promotion and product sales are jointly determined by estimating in-
`strumental variables (IV) models where all three variables are assumed
`to be endogenous. Three sets of variables serve as the basis for our
`exclusion restrictions in the IV specifications for the product specific
`demand equations. The first is the time left on the patent for each drug
`(and its square). This is based on the notion that for products reaching
`the end of their patent protection period, there is little incentive to in-
`vest in promotion (Frank and Salkever 1992; Berndt, Kyle, and Ling
`2002). The length of the patent life remaining is determined far in ad-
`vance of current sales decisions, and there is no direct effect on sales
`
`

`
`16
`
`Rosenthal, Berndt, Donohue, Epstein, and Frank
`
`because there is no generic competition yet in place for these drugs.
`The second instrument reflects the timing of the FDA's clarification of
`the conditions governing direct to consumer advertising on television
`(and the interaction of that indicator with time). In 1997 the F

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket