throbber
Antitrust, Vol. 28, No. 1, Fall 2013. © 2013 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be
`copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association.
`
`Antitrust Scrutiny of
`Pharmaceutical
`“Product Hopping”
`
`B Y M . S E A N R O Y A L L , A S H L E Y E . J O H N S O N ,
`
`A N D J A S O N C . M C K E N N E Y
`
`PATENT AND ANTITRUST LAWS ALIKE
`
`are meant to encourage innovation, and for good
`reason. The U.S. Patent and Trademark Office
`estimates that innovation has accounted for fully
`three-quarters of post-World War II economic
`expansion in the United States.1 Nonetheless, innovation
`in the form of new products and product enhancements
`has at times been attacked under the antitrust laws, and it
`appears we have reached such a moment in the pharmaceu-
`tical industry.
`Branded and generic manufacturers compete on an annu-
`al basis for roughly $340 billion in U.S. sales and almost $1
`trillion globally.2 As one would hope and expect, this battle
`is waged in part through branded drug company efforts to
`develop and release new, improved (and often patent-pro-
`tected) versions of existing medications. But not all stake-
`holders agree that this is an inherently good thing. Branded
`drug companies have increasingly been accused of violating
`the Sherman Act by using new drug formulations as a tactic
`to blunt competition from generic rivals.
`Such claims have been framed in recent antitrust class
`action lawsuits and in private suits brought by generic com-
`petitors.3 Likewise, the Federal Trade Commission, joining
`various antitrust commentators, has expressed concern that
`the practice of releasing new and improved versions of pre-
`existing drugs—“product hopping” or “product switch-
`ing”—can, in certain circumstances, harm competition by
`complicating or delaying generic entry.4
`All such claims, to some extent, are predicated upon the
`regulatory framework governing Food and Drug Adminis -
`tration (FDA) approval of generic drugs in the United States,
`
`M. Sean Royall is a partner in Gibson Dunn & Crutcher LLP’s Dallas and
`Washington, DC offices and co-chairs the firm’s Antitrust and Trade Regu -
`lation Practice Group. Mr. Royall has represented branded drug manufac-
`turers in a variety of competition disputes and presently represents Sanofi-
`Aventis and Allergan in such matters. Ashley E. Johnson and Jason C.
`McKenney are associates in the firm’s Dallas office and have worked with
`Mr. Royall on various matters representing branded drug manufacturers.
`
`a framework established by the Hatch-Waxman Act and
`related regulations, which define a process by which gener-
`ic drug companies may seek expedited approval to manu-
`facture and sell counterparts to previously approved brand-
`ed medications.5 Most product-hopping antitrust claims in
`effect assert that the branded manufacturer has gamed or
`manipulated the FDA’s regulatory scheme by opportunisti-
`cally shifting resources to a new FDA-approved drug for-
`mulation, while, at the same time, withdrawing support for
`the prior formulation that faces imminent or nascent com-
`petition from generics. The contention is that this type of
`“product shift” or “product hop” can have the effect of
`destroying demand for the generic and thus impeding an
`effective generic product launch. The branded manufactur-
`er’s move to a new drug formulation, the theory goes, serves
`to reset the product market, putting the generic essentially
`back to square one in its efforts to deliver FDA-approved
`equivalents to the marketplace.
`A common contention in such cases is that the generic
`drug companies, which keep their costs low in part by not
`actively marketing their products, are largely at the mercy of
`their branded competitors, whose continued support for the
`branded version of the relevant drug is essentially a prereq-
`uisite for successful generic entry. Most theories of competi-
`tive harm in this area also depend to some extent on skepti-
`cism regarding the improved health benefits of new drug
`formulations—for instance, a change from a lower to a high-
`er dosage, from a capsule to a tablet, or from immediate
`release to extended release.
`This naturally leads to a complicated, and one might say
`troubling, balancing of the social welfare benefits of margin-
`ally improved pharmaceuticals, on the one hand, versus un -
`changed but somewhat less expensive ones on the other. The
`risks entailed by antitrust scrutiny of product innovation are
`well known and largely intuitive,6 but this has not deterred
`courts from entertaining Sherman Act challenges based in sig-
`nificant part on product-hopping allegations. Indeed, in one
`recent case Abbott Laboratories and its co-defendants, after
`losing a motion for summary judgment, paid $250 million in
`part to settle such claims,7 and Warner Chilcott is presently
`defending a similar case in which the plaintiffs are seeking tre-
`ble damages potentially reaching into the billions.8
`The very prospect of a branded drug maker being exposed
`to treble damages linked to the launch of an FDA-approved
`new product formulation would be enough to send chills
`down the spines of many pharmaceutical executives. But the
`present situation is worse still, considering that the courts
`have yet to reach any consensus regarding what standards
`should be applied in judging the merits of such claims.
`In one of the original cases alleging anticompetitive inno-
`vation, the Second Circuit in Berkey Photo held that the suc-
`cessful introduction of a new or improved product, even
`where it arguably undermines competition, should not give
`rise to an antitrust cause of action absent some element of
`“coercion.”9 However, the court did not define precisely
`
`F A L L 2 0 1 3
`

`
` 7 1
`
`Page 1
`
`

`

`A R T I C L E S
`
`what it meant by coercion, and confusion over this issue has
`persisted.10
`Some years later, the D.C. Circuit in Microsoft held that
`product innovations challenged under the antitrust laws
`should be subjected to a form of rule-of-reason balancing,
`with the asserted procompetitive benefits of the product
`improvement being balanced against the alleged anticom-
`petitive effects.11 These seemingly conflicting standards have
`never been fully reconciled, and the resulting confusion can
`be seen in the small handful of court decisions that have
`addressed pharmaceutical product-hopping claims.
`No matter where one stands on the broader issue of prod-
`uct hopping, most would agree that the risks of over-deter-
`rence in this area could be serious, and that caution is war-
`ranted.12 The benefits of generic drug competition are
`naturally quite significant, but the benefits of new and
`improved pharmaceutical product formulations are likewise
`important to our society and economy. The prospect of anti -
`trust courts or agencies weighing these benefits against each
`other is, to the authors, an uncomfortable proposition. And
`such concerns are only heightened by the fact that, at pres-
`ent, there remains significant uncertainty in the law, a situa-
`tion we hope will be corrected by future legal rulings.
`
`The Regulatory Backdrop
`The Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration
`Act of 1984, commonly known as the Hatch-Waxman Act,13
`attempts to strike a balance between two potentially coun-
`tervailing public interests—inducing innovation by branded
`drug companies, and fostering the development of lower-cost
`generic versions of “innovative” or “pioneer” branded drugs.14
`Under FDA rules, a company seeking approval of a new
`pharmaceutical must file a New Drug Application (NDA),
`providing extensive data concerning the efficacy and safety of
`the product, which can be time-consuming and extremely
`expensive.15 Before Hatch-Waxman, an NDA was required
`for all new drugs, including generic versions of previously
`approved branded drugs. But Hatch-Waxman enabled gener-
`ic drug makers to obtain FDA approval through a more
`streamlined Abbreviated New Drug Application (ANDA)
`process that omits the need for clinical trials and other cost-
`ly work required by the standard NDA. Under the FDA’s
`ANDA process, generic drugs may be approved as long as
`they are shown to be “bioequivalent” to a previously approved
`branded drug.16
`Once a generic drug company receives ANDA approval,
`it may commence marketing its product. Most generic drugs,
`however, are not marketed in a traditional sense. Generic
`drug manufacturers customarily do not advertise their prod-
`ucts or employ sizable direct sales teams. The standard gener-
`ic business model, rather than depending on sales and mar-
`keting efforts, relies heavily on requirements imposed by
`state “substitution” laws mandating that pharmacists dis-
`pense an available FDA-approved generic drug, unless oth-
`erwise directed by the prescribing physician.17 Even without
`
`7 2
`

`
` A N T I T R U S T
`
`sales and marketing support, lower priced generic drugs,
`once available, typically attract a significant share of sales
`away from their branded equivalents.18
`Congress recognized that the enactment of a regime facil-
`itating swifter entry for generic drugs could reduce the in -
`centives of branded drug makers to innovate, inasmuch as
`accelerated generic competition might prevent branded man-
`ufacturers from recouping their research, development, and
`marketing costs. To address this concern, the Hatch-Waxman
`Act, among other things, made it easier for branded manu-
`facturers to enforce patents against generic rivals. If the
`ANDA filer wishes to sell its generic product before the expi-
`ration of patents that the branded manufacturer has listed on
`the FDA’s “Orange Book,” the ANDA filer must provide a
`“Paragraph IV certification,” confirming that the ANDA
`product does not infringe or that the relevant patents are oth-
`erwise invalid.19 If the branded manufacturer promptly ini-
`tiates infringement litigation, this then triggers an automat-
`ic 30-month stay of final FDA approval for the generic
`drug.20 Another feature of Hatch-Waxman is that the first
`ANDA filer, once it obtains final FDA approval, is general-
`ly entitled to 180 days of market exclusivity before any later
`ANDA filer with FDA approval is permitted to launch its
`generic product.21
`By any measure, Hatch-Waxman has spawned an enor-
`mous amount of antitrust litigation and related agency
`enforcement activity. The most prevalent complaints to date
`have centered around claims that branded drug companies
`have improperly invoked Hatch-Waxman 30-month stays
`through “sham” patent litigation22 and claims that branded
`and generic rivals have essentially “conspired” through “pay-
`for-delay” patent settlements to forestall the onset of generic
`competition, dividing the alleged gains between them—an
`issue recently addressed by the Supreme Court in FTC v.
`Actavis.23 The law applicable to such patent-related antitrust
`claims has been developing for years, and the standards are
`now reasonably well settled. By contrast, product-hopping
`allegations—the latest antitrust outgrowth of Hatch-Waxman
`—are a relatively recent phenomenon, and the law remains
`very much in flux.
`
`Current State of the Law on Product Hopping
`To the authors’ knowledge, there have only been three phar-
`maceutical product-hopping cases to date that have result-
`ed in substantive court decisions. The first two of these
`cases—one involving the cholesterol drug TriCor24 and the
`other involving the heartburn medications Prilosec and
`Nexium25—dealt with mirror image facts and led to oppo-
`site conclusions, one denying a motion to dismiss and the
`other granting dismissal. From these two decisions alone,
`one might infer that the viability of product-hopping
`antitrust claims turns largely on the strength of the facts,
`including whether the branded manufacturer reinforced its
`switch to a new product formulation by withdrawing the
`prior formulation from the marketplace and thereby arguably
`
`Page 2
`
`

`

`limiting consumer choice. But a third and more recent deci-
`sion, in a case involving the prescription acne medication
`Doryx,26 raises more fundamental questions about the mer-
`its of “novel”27 product-hopping allegations and signals a
`fairly significant degree of skepticism concerning whether a
`branded drug maker’s shift to a new product formulation
`should ever constitute an antitrust violation. As discussed
`below, these decisions taken as whole provide relatively little
`clarity and leave many questions unanswered.
`Teva. Abbott Labsoratories v. Teva Pharmaceuticals USA
`appears to have been the first case to squarely frame an anti -
`trust claim predicated on allegations of pharmaceutical prod-
`uct hopping, and it resulted in a somewhat detailed decision
`denying a motion to dismiss filed by the defendants, the prin-
`cipal defendant being Abbott Laboratories. The plaintiffs
`asserted that Abbott twice changed its formulation for TriCor
`(from a capsule to a tablet and later to a new tablet with
`lower dosage strengths), obtained NDA approval for the prod-
`uct changes, and completed two successive switches to new
`product formulations in a manner strategically timed, in both
`instances, to thwart imminent generic competition for the
`“obsolete” versions of the drug.28 In both instances, the plain-
`tiffs alleged that Abbott not only stopped selling the prior
`version of TriCor, but also took the further step of removing
`the prior formulation from the National Drug Data File
`(NDDF), a private database of FDA-approved drugs. This
`further step, plaintiffs alleged, literally prevented pharmacies
`from filling prescriptions for the superseded formulation or
`any generic equivalents, making generic substitution no longer
`possible.29
`Abbott and its co-defendants, in their motion to dismiss,
`maintained that even the plaintiffs had acknowledged that
`the new formulations reflected improvements, however
`minor, over the prior formulations, and that any product
`change that introduces an improvement must be per se law-
`ful under the antitrust laws.30 The defendants also argued that
`they had no duty to aid competitor. Hence the withdrawal of
`old TriCor formulations, even if highly disruptive to gener-
`ic rivals, cannot violate the Sherman Act.31
`The court in Teva rejected these and other defense argu-
`ments and in so doing set forth what it deemed to be the
`appropriate standard for assessing claims of this nature. The
`starting point for the court’s analysis was the Second Cir cuit’s
`decision in Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co.32 As Teva
`explained, the outcome in Berkey Photo (which reversed a
`plaintiff’s jury verdict) turned on one major logical under-
`pinning—the observation that Kodak’s challenged new prod-
`uct offerings (the Pocket Instamatic camera and related film
`cartridges) had gained “acceptance in the market” purely as
`a consequence of “free choice” by consumers.33 Notably, in
`the view of the Teva court, it was clear from the facts in
`Berk ey Photo that Kodak, upon introducing its new products,
`“did not remove any other films from the market”34; and even
`more notably, the Second Circuit in deciding Berkey Photo
`suggested it might have reached a different outcome had
`
`Abbott Labsoratories v. Teva Pharmaceuticals USA
`
`appears to have been the first case to squarely frame
`
`an anti trust claim predicated on allegations of
`
`pharmaceutical product hopping,
`
`Kodak “ceased producing film in the [old] size, thereby com-
`pelling camera purchasers to buy [the new] camera.”35
`Teva fully embraced this dichotomy between “free choice”
`and “coercion,” and largely on this basis the court deter-
`mined that dismissal was inappropriate, given allegations
`that Abbott removed the prior drug formulations from the
`market and changed the NDDF codes. “[S]uch conduct,” the
`court stated, “results in consumer coercion” and “is poten-
`tially anticompetitive.”36
`It appears that Teva, in line with Berkey Photo, would give
`“judicial deference” to pharmaceutical product shifts that do
`nothing to disrupt “free consumer choice,”37 and in this
`sense the decision may signal an antitrust safe harbor of some
`sort.38 But the borders of any such safe harbor, which would
`turn on distinctions between coercion and free choice, are
`hardly well defined. Under Teva, would a branded drug com-
`pany have grounds for dismissal if the challenged formulation
`change was not accompanied by a change in NDDF codes?
`Would there at least be grounds for dismissal if the prior for-
`mulation of the product was not removed from the market?
`Could it be enough for a plaintiff to defeat dismissal if it
`alleged that the prior formulation, while still available, was no
`longer being actively marketed by the branded manufactur-
`er? Is there some other form of alleged “coercion,” besides
`withdrawing support for superseded product formulations
`that a plaintiff could argue interferes with “free choice” in this
`context? Teva provides no real answers to these questions,
`which is somewhat troubling, considering that it offers the
`most detailed judicial commentary to date on this subject.
`Teva also plunged headlong down a path that the Second
`Circuit in Berkey Photo was cautious to avoid—the path of
`balancing the merits of new product innovations against the
`arguable competitive obstacles such innovations may erect. As
`Teva states, “[T]he Second Circuit refused to weigh the ben-
`efits from Kodak’s introduction of a new camera model and
`film format against the alleged harm from the product intro-
`duction because that weighing had already occurred in the
`marketplace.”39 By contrast, the court in Teva concluded
`that an antitrust inquiry probing and comparing the “bene-
`fits” and “effects” of the defendants’ formulation changes
`would be appropriate, given plaintiffs’ assertion that con-
`sumers were deprived of an unfettered choice.40
`The court in fact was very explicit in concluding that
`claims of this nature—at least claims that fall outside what-
`ever “free choice” safe harbor may exist—should ultimately
`
`F A L L 2 0 1 3
`

`
` 7 3
`
`Page 3
`
`

`

`A R T I C L E S
`
`be decided based on the type of rule-of-reason balancing
`approach adopted by the D.C. Circuit’s decision in United
`States v. Microsoft Corp.41 Hence, Teva (in what may well
`constitute dicta) suggested that the plaintiff in a pharmaceu-
`tical product-hopping case should have an initial burden to
`“show anticompetitive harm from the formulation changes”
`and then “that harm” will “be weighed against any benefits
`presented by” the defendant.42
`Teva, of course, was a motion to dismiss decision and did
`not engage in any actual balancing. But to the extent Teva’s
`suggested approach was adopted by later cases, this too seems
`troubling. Are courts or juries truly in a position to sit in judg-
`ment on the merits, including potential therapeutic benefits,
`of one FDA-approved drug formulation versus another? And
`even to the extent courts have competence to delve into such
`questions, how, as a practical matter, does one balance the
`benefits of a new drug formulation against the arguable
`effects of reduced competition? As noted above, this could
`boil down to a choice between marginally improved phar-
`maceuticals and unchanged but somewhat less expensive ones,
`matters that arguably exceed the purview of traditional anti -
`trust principles.
`Walgreen. Walgreen Co. v. AstraZeneca Pharmaceuti cals,43
`decided two years after Teva, was also a ruling on a motion
`to dismiss. The case involved allegations that AstraZeneca
`shifted its resources and began aggressively promoting a
`newly approved prescription heartburn medication, Nexium,
`just as its longstanding heartburn drug, Prilosec, was near-
`ing the end of its patent protection and beginning to face
`generic competition. The plaintiffs alleged that when Astra -
`Zeneca began promoting and “detailing” Nexium to doctors,
`it ceased promoting and detailing Prilosec, but it did not
`withdraw Prilosec from the market; rather, Prilosec remained
`available as a prescription capsule, and, in a modified form,
`as an over-the-counter drug.44 Nevertheless, the plaintiffs
`contended that AstraZeneca’s efforts to “switch” the market
`from Prilosec, which faced generic competition, to “a virtu-
`ally identical” and “no more effective” patent-protected drug,
`Nexium, constituted a Sherman Act violation.45
`In granting AstraZeneca’s motion to dismiss, the court in
`Walgreen relied heavily on the reasoning in Teva and its
`emphasis on the “critical factor” of consumer choice.46 In
`the court’s view, this factor distinguished the two cases entire-
`ly. Whereas in Teva there were allegations that Abbott “sought
`to defeat competition from generic substitutes” by “deliber-
`ately limit[ing] . . . consumers’ choices,” 47 based on the facts
`as alleged in the complaint AstraZeneca had “added choices”
`by introducing a new drug to compete with its alternative
`drug, Prilosec, with generic substitutes to Prilosec, and with
`heartburn medications offered by other manufacturers.48 Even
`if, as the plaintiffs claimed, patent-protected Nexium was in
`no way superior to Prilosec, Walgreen stressed that nothing
`about antitrust law “requires a product new on the market—
`with or without a patent—to be superior to existing prod-
`ucts.”49 In the court’s words, “Those determinations are left
`
`7 4
`

`
` A N T I T R U S T
`
`to the marketplace.”50 And as for the impact of this product
`switch on the generic competition, the court stated, “The fact
`that a new product siphoned off some of the sales from the
`old product and, in turn, depressed sales of the generic sub-
`stitutes for the old product, does not create an antitrust cause
`of action.”51
`Taken in combination, Teva and Walgreen suggest that
`the introduction of a new FDA-approved prescription drug
`formulation, and the contemporaneous shift in marketing
`support from a prior formulation to the new formulation,
`likely is not enough, taken alone, to support a monopoliza-
`tion complaint, even if the consequence of such a shift is that
`generic competitors achieve a smaller overall share of sales. To
`survive a motion to dismiss, there would need to be, in addi-
`tion, some basis for the plaintiff to credibly allege an actual
`reduction in consumer choice. In Walgreen, there were two
`reasons why this condition was not met. First, AstraZeneca
`did not remove Prilosec from the market; the drug continued
`to be sold, albeit primarily as an over-the-counter drug that
`was not heavily marketed. But secondly and importantly,
`there was no allegation that AstraZeneca’s actions eliminat-
`ed the consumer’s option to choose a generic alternative.
`Indeed, the court’s decision, citing to the complaint, suggests
`that generic manufacturers had collectively achieved a 30
`percent share of sales.52
`Teva and Walgreen therefore deal with somewhat polar
`extremes. In the former case, the asserted facts suggest that
`the defendants effectively eliminated both the prior NDA for-
`mulation of TriCor and any generic equivalents. In the latter
`case, there was no dispute that both the prior formulation
`and its generic equivalents remained readily available for pur-
`chase. Yet there are a number of alternative fact scenarios one
`could envision. For instance, the branded manufacturer, after
`launching a new formulation, may choose to cease actively
`marketing the prior formulation but not immediately remove
`it from the market, and generic entrants in response might
`choose to discontinue their efforts to enter. How courts might
`view this and other potential scenarios is not at all clear based
`on the combined holdings in Teva and Walgreen.
`Mylan. In another ongoing product-hopping antitrust
`suit, Mylan Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Warner Chilcott Public
`Limited Co., the district court recently denied a motion to
`dismiss.53 Interestingly the court’s order placed no reliance on
`either Teva or Walgreen, and seemed to signal views at odds
`with the approaches adopted by those prior decisions.
`The asserted facts in Mylan fall somewhere between the
`fact patterns presented in Teva and Walgreen. The complaint
`alleges that Warner Chilcott and its co-defendants engaged in
`a conscious strategy to prevent or delay generic competition
`for the company’s branded Doryx medication by executing
`at least three distinct product switches—first from a capsule
`to a tablet, then from 75mg and 100mg tablets to a single
`150mg dosage strength, and finally from a single-scored ver-
`sion of the 150mg tablet to a dual-scored version.54 “[T]hese
`switches,” the complaint alleges, provided “little or no ther-
`
`Page 4
`
`

`

`The Mylan cour t’s dismissal decision, while perhaps
`
`sending a promising sign to those who oppose
`
`antitrust scrutiny of product hopping, does little
`
`to clarify the law.
`
`apeutic benefit to consumers,” but “devastated the market for
`the prior versions of Doryx,” which Warner Chilcott ceased
`promoting and eventually withdrew from the market, there-
`by “forc[ing] generic manufacturers such as Mylan to change
`their products in development” in an effort to align their
`generic offerings with the currently promoted version of the
`branded drug.55 Unlike Teva, however, there is no allegation
`in Mylan that Warner Chilcott changed NDDF codes in a
`manner that might preclude generic substitution. In fact,
`the complaint appears to acknowledge that Mylan success-
`fully developed and at least initially launched several gener-
`ic formulations.56
`In moving to dismiss, the defendants argued, among other
`things, that Mylan’s claims boiled down to a contention that
`branded drug companies have a duty to continue promoting
`outdated formulations to permit generic competitors to take
`advantage of automatic substitution laws. But, the defen-
`dants maintained, nothing in the antitrust laws suggests that
`such a duty either does or should exist.57 On the contrary, the
`defendants argued, antitrust law suggests that this type of
`“free riding” is “‘the antithesis of competition.’”58
`The defendants also used their motion to dismiss to make
`a pointed attack against Mylan and its generic business
`model. In the opening paragraphs of their motion, the defen-
`dants contend that Mylan is one of the world’s largest phar-
`maceutical companies, fully twice the size of Warner Chilcott,
`and that the company has ample resources to actively pro-
`mote its generic products without relying entirely on state
`substitution laws, if it so chose.59
`Had the court in Mylan followed the approach of Teva and
`Walgreen, it might have focused on Warner Chilcott’s alleged
`decisions to phase out prior formulations and the extent to
`which this deprived consumers of choices. But there is no
`mention of such concepts in the Mylan dismissal order. The
`court instead summarized the defendants’ principal grounds
`for dismissal, and commented that “[d]efendants’ con-
`tentions, if correct, appear compelling.”60 This included the
`defendants’ claims that “their product changes . . . did noth-
`ing to block generic firms from competing” but “merely pre-
`cluded generic firms from taking advantage of automatic
`substitution laws”; the defendants’ contention that if “gener-
`ic firms cannot advertise their products to compete success-
`fully with Doryx” this may simply “reveal a problem with the
`generics’ business models” or with the relevant “regulatory
`regimes”; and the defendants’ overarching claim that Mylan’s
`product-hopping theory, which the court characterized as
`
`“‘novel’ at best,” fails to state “an antitrust injury.”61 In clos-
`ing, the court’s order stated, “Although I am skeptical that
`the ‘product hopping’ alleged here constitutes anticompeti-
`tive conduct under the Sherman Act, I cannot definitively
`address that question without going beyond the pleadings.”62
`This was, to say the least, a marked departure from Walgreen
`and Teva.
`The Mylan court’s dismissal decision, while perhaps send-
`ing a promising sign to those who oppose antitrust scrutiny
`of product hopping, does little to clarify the law. Indeed, if
`anything, the dramatically different tone struck by the court’s
`decision in comparison to Teva and Walgreen underscores
`how far we are at present from anything approaching a judi-
`cial consensus.
`
`The FTC’s Stance on Product Hopping
`FTC interest in the product-hopping issue dates back to at
`least 2006. In that year, the FTC filed a preliminary injunc-
`tion motion in federal court seeking to bar Warner Chilcott
`from following through with an apparent plan to withdraw
`an existing tablet formulation of its birth control product
`Ovcon coinciding with the launch of a new chewable version
`of the same product.63 The issue arose in connection with an
`already pending suit in which the FTC’s complaint alleged
`that Warner Chilcott and generic manufacturer Barr Pharma -
`ceuticals had entered an agreement that would serve to delay
`generic competition for Ovcon. And the final order by which
`the litigation was settled included additional terms that in
`essence required Warner Chilcott to continue supporting the
`non-chewable tablet form of Ovcon, including requirements
`that Warner Chilcott not change the relevant NDDF codes
`or, for a period of three months, destroy inventory or buy
`back product already distributed to customers.64
`The product-hopping issue has also surfaced at times in
`statements by various FTC commissioners. In 2007, then-
`FTC Chairman Deborah Platt Majoras, in a carefully word-
`ed statement, flagged the issue as one the Commission was
`“following.”65 A year later, then-FTC Commissioner and
`former FTC Chairman Jon Leibowitz signaled a potentially
`greater degree of FTC concern, mentioning product hopping
`as one example of “strategies used in connection with launch-
`ing a new [pharmaceutical] product” that “seem to serve no
`purpose other than to undermine the ability of a generic to
`compete.”66 Leibowitz also suggested, consistent with the
`general subject of his remarks, that this could be an area
`where it might “make sense to apply” the FTC’s expanded
`Section 5 enforcement authority.67
`Most recently, in late 2012 the agency took the unusual
`step of filing a fairly lengthy amicus brief in connection with
`the district court’s consideration of Warner Chilcott’s motion
`to dismiss in the Mylan case.68 The stated purposes of the
`brief were to present “background and analysis” on the nature
`and importance of generic competition and to address “the
`appropriate antitrust framework” for evaluating claims that
`“a brand drug reformulation unlawfully delayed or inhibit-
`
`F A L L 2 0 1 3
`

`
` 7 5
`
`Page 5
`
`

`

`A R T I C L E S
`
`ed generic competition.”69 But the brief went further. For
`instance, quoting the views of a prominent antitrust com-
`mentator, the Commission stated, “‘Product-hopping seems
`clearly to be an effort to game the rather intricate FDA rules
`. . . . The patentee is making a product change with no tech-
`nological benefit solely in order to delay competition.’”70
`The FTC brief also took a stand on the merits, at least
`insofar as it voiced the opinion that Mylan’s complaint “stat-
`ed a plausible claim.”71 As for the appropriate legal standard,
`the FTC hewed closely to the framework adopted by the
`district court’s decision in Teva, which it cited liberally, and
`argued somewhat forcefully that an approach that might
`deem product reformulations “per se lawful” would “entitle
`brand pharmaceutical companies . . . to manipulate the FDA
`regulatory process and undermine state and federal laws that
`encourage generic competition.”72
`Interestingly, the court’s dismissal order in Mylan did not
`so much as mention the FTC’s amicus submission, nor did
`it appear to adopt any of the FTC’s views. On the contrary,
`the decision, if anything, points in the direction of per se
`legality, a position the FTC pointedly attacked. While the
`brief therefore may have had little effect on the outcome of
`that dispute, it does presumably communicate a great deal
`about internal FTC views on the product-hopping issue.
`
`Conclusion
`The Hatch-Waxman Act was designed to strike a delicate
`balance between the interests of generic and branded drug
`manufacturers, duly recognizing both the value of pharma-
`ceutical innovation and the benefits of low-cost generic com-
`petition. In the years since Hatch-Waxman was implement-
`ed, there has been a steady stream of antitrust disputes, many
`of them patent-related, tied in some way to the FDA’s gener-
`ic drug approval process, and this trend shows no signs of
`abating.
`For the most part, it does not appear that such patent-
`related antitrust claims pose any direct threat to the integri-
`ty of the Hatch-Waxman regulatory scheme or its underlying
`policy objectives. In this sense, product-hopping claims, the
`latest antitrust outgrowth of Hatch-Waxman, may be differ-
`e

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket