throbber
(cid:43) (cid:50)(cid:40)(cid:44)(cid:49) (cid:49)(cid:47)(cid:44)(cid:49)(cid:40)
`
`Citation: 108 Colum. L. Rev. 1471 2008
`
`Content downloaded/printed from
`HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org)
`Mon Dec 29 11:24:45 2014
`
`-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance
` of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license
` agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License
`
`-- The search text of this PDF is generated from
` uncorrected OCR text.
`
`-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope
` of your HeinOnline license, please use:
`
` https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do?
` &operation=go&searchType=0
` &lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0010-1958
`
`Page 1
`
`

`

`AN ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT HOPPING IN
`THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY
`
`Jessie Cheng
`
`Trinko emphasized the importance of attention to an industry's regula-
`tory regime in determining the role of antitrust law and suggested a possible
`"expansion of the contours" of the Sherman Act in certain regulatory con-
`texts. This Note explores Trinko's implications for antitrust enforcement in
`the pharmaceutical industry which, though heavily regulated, lacks an in-
`dustry regulator that polices competition. It focuses on product hopping, a
`strategy launched by manufacturers of brand name drugs to undermine com-
`petition from generic substitutes. Parties have challenged product hopping as
`anticompetitive, and the judicial treatment thus far has hinged on the pres-
`ence of consumer coercion. However, such an approach disregards the phar-
`maceutical industry's unique market structure and its regulatory regime.
`This Note inquires into the real anticompetitive harm from product hopping
`through the lens of Trinko. It proposes that courts undertake the antitrust
`analysis with an eye toward the industry's regulatory regime--particularly,
`state drug product selection (DPS) laws-and the legislative policy judgment
`it embodies, in addition to engaging such traditional antitrust concerns as
`promoting innovation and preserving free competition. This Note develops a
`framework that gives manufacturers freedom to innovate, responds to the
`limits of antitrust law, and punishes product hoppers that subvert the spe-
`cific type of competition state legislatures sought to establish in fashioning
`DPS laws.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`On August 2, 2001, Eli Lilly lost its patent protection on Prozac and
`with it, $2.4 billion in annual U.S. sales.' Eli Lilly's drop in Prozac sales
`and loss of market share from generic entry were the most severe Big
`Pharma had yet experienced. 2 In the prescription drug market, a patent
`holder-usually the brand name drug manufacturer that developed the
`pioneer drug, like Eli Lilly-has time-limited, exclusive rights to market
`
`1. Bethany McLean, A Bitter Pill, Fortune, Aug. 13, 2001, at 118, 119; see also Eli Lilly
`and Co., 2001 Annual Report 1 (2001) (observing that sales fell faster than expected);
`John Simons, Lilly Goes Off Prozac, Fortune, June 28, 2004, at 179, 180 (discussing sixty-six
`percent drop in Prozac sales by end of fourth quarter of 2001).
`2. Lilly to Miss 4Q '02 Marks, CNN.com, Oct. 3, 2001, at http://edition.cnn.com/
`(on file with the Columbia Law Review). For a
`2001/BUSINESS/10/03/lilly/index.html
`in the
`losses from patent expiration more recently witnessed
`discussion of severe
`pharmaceutical industry, see generally Selena Class, Pharma Reformulates, 83 Chemical &
`Engineering News 15 (2005) (discussing Pfizer's antidepressant Zoloft, Merck's cholesterol
`reducing drug Zocor, Sanofi-Aventis's sleep aid Ambien, Bristol-Myers Squibb's cholesterol
`reducing drug Pravachol, Novartis's antifungal drug Lamisil, and GlaxoSmithKline's
`antinausea drug Zofran).
`
`1471
`
`Page 2
`
`

`

`1472
`
`COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW
`
`[Vol. 108:1471
`
`its patented drug,3 allowing it to realize hefty profits. 4 Upon the patent's
`expiration or a finding of its invalidity, 5 market competition replaces the
`previously lawful monopoly: Manufacturers of generic drugs (generic
`manufacturers) enter the market, and the incumbent brand name manu-
`facturer may face a steep drop in profits and market share.6 State drug
`product selection (DPS) laws further fuel the erosion of the brand name
`manufacturer's market share by allowing and sometimes requiring phar-
`macies to fill prescriptions for brand name drugs with their rival generic
`7
`equivalents.
`Brand name manufacturers anticipating the loss of patent protection
`may launch strategies to stave off competition from generic manufactur-
`ers ("generic competition") and thereby maintain their high volume of
`sales. This Note investigates one new tactic, product hopping, that has
`recently emerged among brand name manufacturers and explores its po-
`tential for manipulating the pharmaceutical industry's regulatory struc-
`ture while undermining generic competition.
`Product hopping brand name manufacturers ("product hoppers")
`make a slight alteration to their prescription drug and engage in market-
`ing efforts to shift consumers from the old version to the new.8 Generic
`manufacturers must follow the hop to the new version in order to realize
`and maintain a high volume of sales.9 The delay to generic manufactur-
`ers from developing a new generic equivalent and obtaining FDA ap-
`proval to market it allows the product hopper to insulate itself from ge-
`neric competition for several years.' 0
`Though product hopping amounts to little more than a thinly dis-
`guised scheme to manipulate the pharmaceutical industry's regulatory
`system and frustrate generic competition, this new and controversial strat-
`egy is not necessarily an easy target for antitrust enforcement." While
`one antitrust court has denied a defendant pharmaceutical company's
`
`3. See infra note 22 and accompanying text (describing protection under Patent Act).
`4. See infra note 28 and accompanying text (reporting profit margins for drugs under
`patent protection).
`5. See infra note 29 (discussing bases for patent invalidity).
`6. See infra note 30 and accompanying text (reporting substantial discounts for
`generic drugs from price at which brand name drugs are typically sold).
`7. See infra Part I.B (describing generic substitution under state DPS laws and its
`development).
`8. See infra notes 99-101 and accompanying text (giving overview of basic product
`hopping strategy).
`9. See infra notes 102-105 and accompanying text (describing need for generic
`manufacturers to follow product hoppers in order to rely on generic substitution).
`10. See infra note 107 and accompanying text (identifying and explaining delays to
`generic competition from product hopping).
`11. See infra Part II.D (framing anticompetitive harm from product hopping and
`challenges
`to antitrust enforcement);
`infra Part
`III.A.1
`(arguing
`that generic
`manufacturers outdone by their brand name rivals in advertising cannot invoke antitrust
`law to condemn rivals' success); infra Part III.A.2 (cautioning against using antitrust to
`police innovation).
`
`Page 3
`
`

`

`2008]
`
`ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT HOPPING
`
`1473
`
`motion to dismiss a product hopping claim, 12 another court has granted
`a different alleged product hopper's motion to dismiss. 13 Both decisions
`hinged on an inquiry into consumer coercion, 14 which commentators
`have criticized as flawed given the pharmaceutical industry's unique mar-
`ket structure.' 5 Given that product hopping does not implicate any con-
`sumer coercion concerns, this Note asks the essential question: What
`threat to competition does product hopping pose, if any?
`The courts' analysis also overlooked the complex interplay between
`industry's regulatory regime.
`antitrust law and the pharmaceutical
`Neither decision investigated the implications of the Supreme Court's
`2004 decision in Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
`Trinko, LLP.16 Trinko's relevance lies in its recognition of a possible ex-
`panded role for antitrust law in certain regulated industries, potentially
`paving an additional avenue for antitrust law to police product hop-
`ping.17 This Note undertakes the antitrust inquiry with an eye toward the
`pharmaceutical industry's regulatory regime, as Trinko instructs,' 8 and
`the possible harm to competition under the regime that product hopping
`might inflict.
`Part I dissects the pharmaceutical industry's complex regulatory re-
`gime and the relationship it creates between brand name and generic
`manufacturers. It discusses the controversial strategies brand name man-
`ufacturers employ to protect their profits from generic competition and
`highlights the harm these tactics may inflict on market competition, as
`well as consumer welfare. Part II introduces product hopping as one
`such strategy and discusses its judicial treatment in Abbott Laboratories v.
`Inc.19 and Walgreen Co. v. AstraZeneca
`Teva Pharmaceuticals USA,
`Pharmaceuticals L.P.20 It concludes with a critique of this judicial treat-
`ment and questions the courts' underlying assumptions. Part III pro-
`
`12. Abbott Labs. v. Teva Pharms. USA, Inc., 432 F. Supp. 2d 408, 426 (D. Del. 2006);
`see infra notes 154-169 and accompanying text (discussing Abbott and rationale underlying
`decision to deny motion to dismiss).
`13. Walgreen Co. v. AstraZeneca Pharms. L.P., 534 F. Supp. 2d 146, 153 (D.D.C.
`2008); see infra notes 170-171 and accompanying text (discussing Walgreen and court's
`distinguishing of facts from Abbott).
`14. See infra notes 165-167 and accompanying text (examining Abbott court's finding
`of consumer coercion); infra notes 170-171 and accompanying text (discussing Walgreen
`court's conclusion that there was no consumer coercion).
`15. See infra Part II.F (analyzing pharmaceutical industry's market structure and
`observing that product hopping does not jeopardize consumer free choice).
`16. 540 U.S. 398 (2004).
`17. See infra note 230 and accompanying text (noting Trinko's recognition of possible
`expansion of contours of antitrust law). But see Daniel F. Spulber & Christopher S. Yoo,
`Mandating Access to Telecom and the Internet: The Hidden Side of Trinko, 107 Colum. L.
`Rev. 1822, 1825, 1869-71 (2007) (noting disagreement among courts and commentators
`regarding Trinko's scope).
`18. See infra notes 211, 228 and accompanying text (describing interaction between
`antitrust law and regulatory regime in light of Trinko).
`19. 432 F. Supp. 2d 408 (D. Del. 2006).
`20. 534 F. Supp. 2d 146 (D.D.C. 2008).
`
`Page 4
`
`

`

`1474
`
`COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW
`
`[Vol. 108:1471
`
`poses an analysis of product hopping's anticompetitive harm that departs
`from the current standard under Abbott and Walgreen. Its proposed
`framework responds to the limits of antitrust law and engages the role of
`antitrust law in regulated industries, as well as recognizes and reflects the
`pharmaceutical
`industry's unique market structure and regulatory
`regime.
`
`I. THE PLAYING FIELD: THE PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY'S
`REGULATORY REGIME
`This Part provides an overview of the complex regulatory regime gov-
`erning generic and brand name manufacturers in the pharmaceutical in-
`dustry. Part L.A examines federal prescription drug regulation and the
`incentive structure it establishes. Part I.B traces the development of state
`prescription drug regulation and the generic substitution it promotes.
`Part I.C discusses the interaction between the pharmaceutical industry's
`complex regulatory structure and the competitive strategies brand name
`manufacturers have launched against their generic rivals.
`
`A. Federal Regulation of Prescription Drugs
`1. Developing and Marketing Prescription Drugs. - Brand name manu-
`facturers supply the innovation for prescription drugs by heavily investing
`in research and development of new products. 2' Patent law rewards
`these innovating manufacturers by granting them time-limited exclusive
`rights to market and sell their pioneer drug.2 2 However, antitrust laws,
`
`21. Experts estimate $500 million to $2 billion in costs for bringing new drugs to
`market. Billion Dollar Pills, Economist, Jan. 27, 2007, at 69, 69; see also Henry G.
`Grabowski, John Vernon & Joseph A. DiMasi, Returns on Research and Development for
`1990s New Drug Introductions, 20 PharmacoEconomics (Supp. 3) 11, 22-23 (2002)
`(noting that only about one-third of marketed drugs generate revenues that match or
`exceed average research and development costs); Pharm. Research & Mfrs. of Am.,
`Innovation, at http://www.phrma.org/innovation (last visited Aug. 18, 2008) (on file with
`the Columbia Law Review) ("Only one of every 10,000 potential medicines investigated by
`America's research-based pharmaceutical companies makes it through the research and
`development pipeline and is approved for patient use by the [FDA]."). But see Pub.
`Citizen's Cong. Watch, Rx R&D Myths: The Case Against the Drug Industry's R&D "Scare
`Card," at i, 5-7 (2001), available at http://www.citizen.org/documents/acfdc.pdf (on file
`with the Columbia Law Review) (disputing Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of
`America's cost estimates and arguing that "the $500 million [cost estimate]
`includes
`significant expenses that are tax deductible and unrealistic scenarios of risks" such that
`"actual cash outlay for a new drug is ...
`as low as $57 million per drug in [the 1990s]
`(including failures)").
`22. 35 U.S.C. § 271 (2000). Patent exclusivity provides the incentive to innovate,
`which is particularly needed where intellectual property, as a public good, tends to be
`underproduced and subject to free riders. Michael A. Carrier, Unraveling the Patent-
`Antitrust Paradox, 150 U. Pa. L. Rev. 761, 767-68 (2002); see also Frank H. Easterbrook,
`Foreword: The Court and the Economic System, 98 Harv. L. Rev. 4, 21-29 (1984)
`(describing Supreme Court's historic treatment of ex ante perspective on intellectual
`property). For a contrast to ex ante justifications for patent protection, see Edmund W.
`Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & Econ. 265, 276 (1977)
`
`Page 5
`
`

`

`2008]
`
`ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT HOPPING
`
`1475
`
`particularly the Sherman Act,23 prevent patent holding manufacturers
`from exploiting their patent-conferred monopoly to improperly harm
`competitors and threaten consumer welfare. 24
`Under the Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act (FFDCA), manu-
`facturers must obtain market approval from the FDA before their new
`drugs can reach the shelves. 25 Brand name manufacturers may do so by
`submitting a new drug application (NDA) to the FDA for their pioneer
`drug.26 The FDA grants approval upon a determination of the pioneer
`drug's safety and efficacy.2 7 The brand name manufacturer may then
`
`(justifying broad patent rights as key to efficiently coordinating invention's subsequent
`development). Under the Patent Act, to obtain patent protection, manufacturers must
`submit to the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office a specification that satisfies the statutory
`requirements of subject matter, utility, novelty, and nonobviousness.
`35 U.S.C.
`§§ 101-103, 112; see also Amgen, Inc. v. Chugai Pharm. Co., 927 F.2d 1200, 1209-10 (Fed.
`Cir. 1991) (construing 35 U.S.C. § 112).
`23. Antitrust's basic law, the Sherman Act, has two major provisions. Section 1
`purports to condemn "[e]very contract, combination . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of
`trade." 15 U.S.C. § 1 (2000). Section 2 forbids a person or a combination of persons from
`attempting or conspiring to "monopolize." Id. § 2. Its goals include fostering innovation
`and promoting competition and consumer welfare. Antitrust Modernization Comm'n,
`Report and Recommendations, at ii (2007); Robert H. Bork, The Role of the Courts in
`Applying Economics, 54 Antitrust L.J. 21, 24 (1985); infra note 186 and accompanying text
`(identifying free and vigorous competition as focus of Sherman Act).
`24. The Patent Act does not grant patentees "carte blanche" in the exercise of their
`rights, including immunity from antitrust laws. Louis Kaplow, The Patent-Antitrust
`Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97 Harv. L. Rev. 1813, 1817-18 (1984). As the goals of the
`Sherman Act, see supra note 23, may conflict with the exercise of patent rights, courts and
`commentators have attempted to balance antitrust laws and the Patent Act, refusing to
`allow one to trump the other. See Simpson v. Union Oil Co., 377 U.S. 13, 24 (1964) ("The
`patent laws which give a 17-year monopoly on 'making, using, or selling the invention' are
`in pati materia with the antitrust laws and modify them pro tanto."); In re Indep. Serv. Orgs.
`Antitrust Litig., 203 F.3d 1322, 1325 (Fed. Cir. 2000) ("Intellectual property rights do not
`confer a privilege to violate the antitrust laws .... [Nor do] antitrust laws ... negate the
`patentee's right to exclude others from patent property.").
`25. 21 U.S.C. §§ 355-395 (2000).
`26. An NDA includes information on the drug's chemical structure, safety, efficacy,
`and toxicology, as well as all animal and human data for the drug and analyses of that data.
`Ctr. for Drug Evaluation & Research, FDA, New Drug Application (NDA) Process, available
`at http://www.fda.gov/cder/regulatory/applications/NDA.htm (last visited Aug. 18, 2008)
`(on file with the Columbia Law Review) [hereinafter FDA, New Drug Process]; see also 21
`C.F.R. §314.53(c)(2)
`(2008)
`(describing
`reporting
`requirements
`for new drug
`applications). The goal of the NDA is to provide enough information to permit the FDA
`to determine whether the drug is safe and effective, whether its proposed labeling is
`appropriate, and whether the methods used in manufacturing the drug are adequate to
`preserve its identity, strength, quality, and purity. FDA, New Drug Process, supra; see also
`Ctr. for Drug Evaluation & Research, FDA, NDA Review Process Application, available at
`http://www.fda.gov/cder/handbook/nda.htm (last visited Aug. 18, 2008) (on file with the
`Columbia Law Review) (providing flow chart for NDA review process).
`27. An FDA
`review
`team-consisting of doctors,
`chemists,
`statisticians,
`microbiologists, pharmacologists, and other experts-evaluates whether
`the NDA
`establishes that the drug is safe and effective for use, where "safe" means that the drug's
`benefits outweigh its risks. The review team also scrutinizes the study's design, results, and
`
`Page 6
`
`

`

`1476
`
`COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW
`
`[Vol. 108:1471
`
`proceed to market its drug, enjoying the supercompetitive profits associ-
`ated with its patent-granted market exclusivity. 28
`However, once a drug's patent protection expires or is found to be
`invalid,29 the brand name manufacturer loses its market exclusivity and
`faces competition. The most potent threat to profits comes from generic
`manufacturers, 30 who can produce equivalents of off-patent brand name
`drugs3 1 without incurring the high research and development costs of
`drug discovery.3 2
`
`conclusions. Michelle Meadows, The FDA's Drug Review Process: Ensuring Drugs are Safe
`and Effective, FDA Consumer, July-Aug. 2002, at 19, 19, 22-23.
`28. Typical gross margins for drugs enjoying patent protection range from ninety to
`ninety-five percent. Barbara Martinez & Jacob Goldstein, Big Pharma Faces Grim
`Prognosis: Industry Fails To Find New Drugs To Replace Wonders Like Lipitor, Wall St.J.,
`Dec. 6, 2007, at Al.
`29. A patent may be found invalid for failing to comply with one or more of the
`requirements of 35 U.S.C. §§ 101-103, 112
`(2000), namely utility, novelty, and
`nonobviousness.
`30. The first generic entrant typically charges a price twenty to thirty percent lower
`than the brand name manufacturer's; as additional generic manufacturers enter the
`market, the price may drop to half of the brand price or less. Competition in the
`Pharmaceutical Marketplace: Antitrust Implications of Patent Settlements: Hearing
`Before the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, 107th Cong. 5 (2001) (statement of Molly Boast,
`Director, FTC), available at http://judiciary.senate.gov/oldsite/te052401mb.pdf (on file
`with the Columbia Law Review) (citing Cong. Budget Office, How Increased Competition
`from Generic Drugs Has Affected Prices and Returns in the Pharmaceutical Industry
`(1998)); see also Henry G. Grabowski & John M. Vernon, Brand Loyalty, Entry, and Price
`Competition in Pharmaceuticals After the 1984 Drug Act, 35 J.L. & Econ. 331, 335-36 &
`tbl.1 (1992) (observing that generic drugs enter at a "significant discount" to competing
`brand name drugs and that "there is a strong downward price dynamic over time" for
`generic drugs). But note a controversial type of generic product not discussed in this Note
`that instead helps brand name manufacturers defuse the threat of generic competition:
`"authorized" or "branded" generics, whereby brand name manufacturers issue, threaten to
`issue, or authorize a distributor to issue a generic version of their own prescription drug in
`order to discourage market entry by generic manufacturers. Bureau of Consumer Prot.,
`FTC, Drug Product Selection 48 (1979) [hereinafter FTC, DPS]; Saami Zain, Sword or
`Shield? An Overview and Competitive Analysis of the Marketing of "Authorized Generics,"
`62 Food & Drug LJ. 739, 744-46 (2007); Leila Abboud, Drug Makers Use New Tactic To
`Ding Generics, Wall St. J., Jan. 27, 2004, at BI.
`31. Generic drugs are defined as drugs that are "identical, or bioequivalent to a brand
`name drug in dosage form, safety, strength, route of administration, quality, performance
`characteristics and intended use." Office of Generic Drugs, FDA, at http://www.fda.gov/
`cder/ogd/#Introduction
`(last visited Aug. 18, 2008) (on file with the Columbia Law
`Review). However, therapeutically equivalent drugs may still vary in characteristics such as
`color, shape, taste, or packaging. Therapeutically Equivalent Drugs; Availability of List, 45
`Fed. Reg. 72,582, 72,586, 72,589 (Oct. 31, 1980).
`32. FTC, DPS, supra note 30, at 13-14 ("[Generic manufacturers] do litfle new drug
`development or promotion, but usually specialize primarily in producing unbranded (i.e.,
`not bearing a brand name) versions of... drugs."); see Eli Lilly & Co. v. Medtronic, Inc.,
`496 U.S. 661, 676 (1990) (observing that abbreviated FDA approval procedures "permit an
`applicant seeking approval of a generic drug to avoid the costly and time-consuming
`studies required for a pioneer drug"). But note that generic manufacturers must
`nevertheless invest time and money into developing a formulation, testing the product,
`and obtaining product approval, which takes multiple review cycles. Richard J. Findlay,
`
`Page 7
`
`

`

`2008]
`
`ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT HOPPING
`
`1477
`
`To enter the market as cheaper substitutes for their brand name
`counterparts, generic manufacturers must submit an abbreviated new
`drug application (ANDA) to the FDA for their generic drug. 33 Because
`brand name manufacturers have already demonstrated the safety and effi-
`cacy of their drug in their NDA, there is no need for generic manufactur-
`ers to undertake duplicative trials to establish their equivalent drug's
`safety and efficacy.3 4 Rather, in their ANDAs, generic manufacturers
`(1) provide information to show that the new drug is the
`need only:
`same as its brand name counterpart (the "reference listed drug"3 5 ) with
`respect to active ingredient or ingredients, route of administration, dos-
`age form, strength, and labeling, with certain exceptions;36 (2) establish
`that the generic product is the bioequivalent of the reference listed
`drug;37 and (3) complete one of four ANDA certifications.3 8
`
`Originator Drug Development, 54 Food & Drug L.J. 227, 229 (1999) (describing generic
`product development cycle as requiring an upfront investment of $1,000,000, six to
`eighteen months for product development, six to twelve months for bioequivalency testing,
`and eighteen to thirty months for FDA approval).
`33. 21 U.S.C. § 355(a), (j) (2000); Loren Gelber, Obtaining Approval of a Generic
`Drug, in The Pharmaceutical Regulatory Process 415, 416 (Ira R. Berry ed., 2005).
`34. See Purepac Pharm. Co. v. Thompson, 354 F.3d 877, 879 (D.C. Cir. 2004)
`(discussing how ANDAs "piggyback" on safety and effectiveness information submitted in
`NDAs); Therapeutically Equivalent Drugs; Availability of List, 45 Fed. Reg. at 72,590 ("FDA
`believes it is neither in the interest of the public health nor a productive use of the nation's
`scarce research resources to require costly duplication of tests. A regulatory system that
`requires such duplicative testing is wasteful, anticompetitive, scientifically unsound, and
`ethically dubious.");Justina A. Molzon, The Generic Drug Approval Process, 5J. Pharmacy
`& L. 275, 276-77 (1996) (noting that repetition of safety and effectiveness studies by
`generic manufacturers would "contribute little to an understanding of the safety or efficacy
`of the drug entity that was not already know[n]").
`35. 21 C.F.R. § 314.3 (2008) ("Reference listed drug means the listed drug identified by
`FDA as the drug product upon which [a generic] applicant relies in seeking approval of its
`[ANDA] application."); Eric L. Cramer & Daniel Berger, The Superiority of Direct Proof of
`Monopoly Power and Anticompetitive Effects in Antitrust Cases Involving Delayed Entry of
`Generic Drugs, 39 U.S.F. L. Rev. 81, 119 (2004) (noting that reference listed drugs are
`brand name drugs approved under NDAs and to which ANDA applicants demonstrate
`their products are therapeutically equivalent).
`36. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (2) (A) (ii), (iii), (v).
`37. Id. § 355(j) (2) (A) (iv); see § 355(j) (8) (B) (defining bioequivalence); see also 21
`C.F.R. § 320.1(e) (explaining that drug is bioequivalent if it shows comparable rate and
`extent that active ingredient is absorbed from drug and becomes available at site of
`action); Therapeutically Equivalent Drugs; Availability of List, 45 Fed. Reg. at 72,593
`(discussing how bioequivalence requirement ensures that generic drugs will perform with
`same safety and effectiveness as their FDA-approved brand name counterparts); Ctr. for
`Drug Evaluation & Research, FDA, Approved Drug Products with Therapeutic Equivalence
`(last
`Evaluations, available at http://www.fda.gov/cder/ob/docs/preface/ecpreface.htm
`visited Aug. 18, 2008) (on file with the Columbia Law Review) ("A major premise underlying
`that bioequivalent drug products are therapeutically
`is
`the [Hatch-Waxman Act]
`equivalent and, therefore, interchangeable.").
`38. The applicant would complete a Paragraph I certification if no patent information
`on the reference listed drug has been filed; Paragraph II if the patents claimed by the
`reference listed drug have expired; Paragraph III if the patents claimed by the reference
`listed drug will expire on a stated date; and Paragraph IV if the patents claimed by the
`
`Page 8
`
`

`

`1478
`
`COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW
`
`[Vol. 108:1471
`
`Even while a brand name manufacturer's patent is in effect, generic
`manufacturers may apply for FDA approval to immediately market their
`competing generic product. To do so, the generic manufacturer must
`file an ANDA with a Paragraph IV certification (an "ANDA IV") and es-
`tablish that the patents claimed by the brand name manufacturer's drug
`are invalid or not infringed by the generic product.3 9 The submission of
`an ANDA IV itself allows the brand name manufacturer to bring a suit for
`patent infringement and challenge the ANDA.40 If the brand name man-
`ufacturer does not do so or if the generic manufacturer wins in litigation,
`the generic manufacturer may immediately enter the market upon FDA
`approval41 and capture a substantial portion of its brand name competi-
`tor's market share by offering an attractively cheaper but equally effective
`4 2
`alternative.
`2. The Hatch-Waxman Act. - The ANDA framework is a relatively re-
`cent development formally authorized by the Drug Price Competition
`and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984,43 usually referred to as the
`Hatch-Waxman Act. Congress enacted the Hatch-Waxman Act to achieve
`policy goals tailored to the pharmaceutical industry: (1) to increase the
`availability of low-cost generic drugs and (2) to create new incentives for
`brand name drug manufacturers to make greater investments in research
`and development of new drugs. 4 4
`The Act intensifies generic competition through several mecha-
`nisms. 45 The ANDA framework streamlines the generic drug application
`process, facilitating market entry for generic manufacturers. 4 6 To further
`
`reference listed drug are invalid or will not be infringed by the manufacture, use, or sale of
`the generic. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (2) (A) (vii). Note that while a Paragraph III certification
`concedes that the patents have not expired and approval is not immediately sought, a
`Paragraph IV certification seeks pre-expiration approval and marketing of a generic drug.
`39. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (2) (A) (vii) (IV).
`40. 35 U.S.C. § 271(e) (2) (A) (2000).
`41. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (5) (B) (iii) (establishing that ANDA IV certification is effective
`immediately if no suit is brought, or if suit is brought, it is effective at earliest of: (1) court
`decision that patent is invalid or not infringed, (2) patent's expiration, or (3) thirty
`months from the notice required by § 355(j) (2) (B)).
`42. See Bruce N. Kuhlik, The Assault on Pharmaceutical Intellectual Property, 71 U.
`Chi. L. Rev. 93, 94-96 (2004) (describing factors that make competition from generic
`manufacturers "especially challenging" to brand name manufacturers).
`43. Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. 1585 (1984) (codified as amended at 21 U.S.C. § 355
`and 35 U.S.C. § 271(e)).
`44. H.R. Rep. No. 98-857, pt. 1, at 14-15 (1984), reprinted in 1984 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2647,
`2647-48.
`45. As compensation for its intensification of generic competition, the Act grants
`brand name manufacturers special patent extensions for their new drug discoveries.
`Molzon, supra note 34, at 276 n.5; see also Teresa J. Lechner-Fish, The Hatch-Waxman
`System: Suffering a Plague of Bad Behavior, 5 Hous. Bus. & Tax L.J. 372, 392 (2005) ("The
`patent term extension is equal to one-half the time of the investigational new drug trial
`(IND) period plus the NDA review period.").
`46. See supra notes 33-39 and accompanying text (providing overview of abbreviated
`FDA approval process for generic drugs).
`
`Page 9
`
`

`

`2008]
`
`ANTITRUST ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT HOPPING
`
`1479
`
`encourage generic manufacturers to enter the market and challenge in-
`valid patents, the Hatch-Waxman Act awards time-limited exclusivity
`rights to the first manufacturer to file an ANDA IV.4 7 For 180 days, the
`first filer enjoys exclusive rights to market the generic version of the pre-
`scription drug. 48 The Act's overall impact on generic competition has
`been significant: Consumption of generic drugs increased from 19% of
`prescriptions filled in 1984 when the Act was passed to 47% in 2002.49
`
`B. State Drug Product Selection Laws
`
`Generic substitution under state DPS laws is also a relatively recent
`development. 50 Where a physician prescribes a brand name drug, ge-
`neric substitution allows pharmacists to fill that prescription with a ge-
`neric equivalent.5 1
`Until the mid-1970s, nearly all states required pharmacists to dis-
`pense the exact drug specified by the prescribing physician, even if
`equivalent generic products were available. 52 States had imposed this
`ban on generic substitution to protect the public from the flood of coun-
`terfeit drugs appearing on the market through unknowing or dishonest
`pharmacists. 53 However, as new federal laws neutralized fears of counter-
`feit drugs, states gradually replaced their antisubstitution laws with DPS
`laws in an effort to contain high drug costs. 5 4
`
`47. During the exclusivity period, the FDA cannot approve "any subsequent eligible
`generic applicants." FTC, Generic Drug Entry Prior to Patent Expiration 57 (2002),
`available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/geneicdrugstudy.pdf
`(on file with
`the
`Columbia Law Review) [hereinafter FTC, Generic Drug Entry]; see also Elizabeth Powell-
`Bullock, Gaming the Hatch-Waxman System: How Pioneer Drug Makers Exploit the Law
`to Maintain Monopoly Power in the Prescription Drug Market, 29 J. Legis. 21, 27-28
`(2002)
`(discussing benefits of exclusivity period to generic manufacturers). For a
`discussion of ANDA LVs, see supra notes 38-39 and accompanying text.
`48. 21 U.S.C. § 355(j) (5) (B) (iv). But see § 355(j) (5) (D) (listing circumstances where
`generic manufacturer must forfeit exclusivity period).
`49. FTC, Generic Drug Entry, supra note 47, at I.
`50. See generally FTC, DPS, supra note 30, at 141-55 (giving historic background on
`state regulation of prescription drugs).
`51. Id. at 7.
`52. Id. at 6-7, 150, 155 ("By 1972, virtually every jurisdiction except the District of
`Columbia had enacted some form of antisubstitution law or regulation."). As physicians
`had less familiarity with lower priced generic equivalents and were thus less likely to
`prescribe them by name, pharmacies rarely dispensed generics under an

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket