throbber

`S9982
`
`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`I don’t
`think the Federal Govern-
`guts of their doctors and nurses. I can
`still see them in my mind, struggling
`ment should pick up 100 percent of the
`expense of mandatory evacuations, but
`to keep those hospitals open with the
`city completely underwater and a par—
`I do think, for some period in some par-
`ish underwater. This is for Orleans and
`ishes. particularly those that have
`Jefferson. They still have not been re-
`been very hard hit, that the Govern—
`ment, the Federal Government. if they
`imbursed for the work that they did
`can do it for some of the counties in
`during Katrina.
`Texas, most certainly should consider
`For some reason, we can't get this
`the parishes in Louisiana. So I am
`Congress to understand the importance
`going to submit that as my last plea
`of what those hospitals did during this
`for the RECORD.
`great time of need. So I wish to send
`this in for the RECORD.
`I know it has been a long day, but I
`————-—
`feel as if we got some things accom-
`plished. I don’t know what the schedule
`will be as the leaders decide on how we
`bring this particular Congress
`to a
`close. but I have to say the work of the
`recovery is still going on. It will go on
`for many years. My heart goes out to
`my neighbors from Texas who are just
`now discovering with awe and shock,
`shock and awe, what a hurricane can
`mean. They haven't had one in 50
`years, such as the one in Galveston.
`and they had one last week. So I know
`what they are experiencing because we
`have been through that. I will stand
`ready to work with them in my com-
`mittee, as chair of the Subcommittee
`on Disaster, when we return. Whether
`it is floods in the Midwest or hurri-
`canes in the gulf. we will continue to,
`first, try to protect ourselves by better
`levees and flood control; and then have
`a better system of aid and help that is
`reliable and dependable for these peo-
`ple—for our people. our constituents,
`and our citizens in need.
`——-————
`
`September 27, 2008
`dium—to-long term. Reputable econo-
`mists estimate that historically. be-
`tween 35 and 40 percent of U.S. produc-
`tivity growth has been the result of in-
`novation.
`My bill makes substantial changes to
`those sections of S. 1145 that address
`damages, post grant review, venue and
`interlocutory appeals, applicant qual-
`ity submissions. and inequitable con-
`duct. This bill will not be considered in
`this Congress. I nevertheless thought
`that it would be useful to propose al-
`ternative approaches to these issues
`now. to allow Senators and interested
`parties the time to consider these al—
`ternatives as we prepare for the patent
`reform debate in the next Congress. I
`hope that my colleagues will work with
`me in a bipartisan and deliberative
`manner to construct a bill that will be
`considered in the next Congress. With
`those thoughts in mind, allow me to
`describe the significant changes that
`this bill makes to S. 1145.
`I believe that S. 1145 goes too far in
`restricting a patent owner’s right to
`recover
`reasonable royalty damages.
`On the other hand. I also believe that
`there is room for improvement in cur-
`rent law. Some unsound practices have
`crept into U.S. patent damages litiga—
`tion. My staff and I spent
`several
`months at the end of last year and the
`beginning of this year discussing the
`current state of patent damages litiga-
`tion with a number of seasoned practi—
`tioners and even some professional
`damages experts.
`I sought out people
`with deep experience in the field who
`had not been retained to lobby on pend-
`ing legislation.
`A substantial number of the experts
`with whom I spoke said that there is
`nothing wrong with current damages
`litigation and that Congress should not
`change the law. Others, however, iden-
`tified a number of unsound practices
`that they believe have led to inflated
`damages awards in a significant num—
`ber of cases. Different attorneys and
`experts repeatedly identified the same
`valuation methods
`and criteria as
`being unsound, subject
`to manipula-
`tion, and leading to damages awards
`that are far out of proportion to an in-
`vention’s economic contribution to the
`infringing product. Examples of prob-
`lematic methodologies that were iden-
`tified to me include the so-called rule
`of thumb, under which an infringed
`patent is presumptively entitled to 40
`percent or some other standard portion
`of all of the profits on a product, the
`use of the average license paid for pat-
`ents in an industry as a starting point
`for calculating the value of a par-
`ticular patent. and a formula attrib-
`uted to IBM whereby every high-tech-
`nology patent is entitled to 1 percent
`of the revenues on a product. A number
`of experts also criticized the use of
`comparables. whereby the value of a
`patent is calculated by reference to the
`license paid for a supposedly com—
`parable patent.
`The views of these experts who were
`critical of current damages law find
`
`DISASTER DECLARATION
`fi-
`Ms. LANDRIEU. Mr. President.
`nally, I wish to urge this administra-
`tion to provide a loo-percent disaster
`declaration for at least these parishes.
`Our Governor has asked for 100 percent
`for all the parishes—and I am going to
`put up that chart in a minute—but the
`Governor believes the entire State de-
`serves to have a loo-percent reimburse-
`ment because Gustav went through our
`whole State. and then Ike came up a
`few weeks later and flooded and did a
`tremendous amount of wind damage.
`We are not designated as a loo-per-
`cent cost share yet, which means the
`Federal Government would step in and
`pick up 100 percent of some of these
`parishes that are on their last
`leg.
`They have been through four storms in
`the last couple years. Unfortunately,
`and I am not sure why, but several
`counties in Texas have been granted
`the first 0 to 14 days at 100 percent. Yet
`our parishes. which were hit equally as
`hard. have not yet received that des-
`ignation.
`So I am asking, on their behalf and
`with the full support of our Governor,
`our Lieutenant Governor, and others
`who are leading our effort in the recov-
`ery. if the administration would please
`consider at least giving equal
`treat-
`ment—100 percent. 0 to 14—for the par-
`ishes that were as hard hit as the Texas
`counties were in this aerial.
`But do not forget, as I close, that
`when Hurricane Gustav was in the gulf.
`our Governor called for a mandatory
`evacuation, and 2 million people, the
`largest evacuation in the country’s his-
`tory, left their homes to move tempo-
`rarily.
`for a couple days. and then
`came back. The damage was very bad.
`It wasn’t catastrophic such as Katrina,
`but it was as bad as Hurricane Rita.
`But when they came home, the Federal
`Government said: Well, thank you for
`evacuating, but there is virtually no
`help for you or your counties.
`It is expensive to evacuate. I know
`people don‘t understand,
`those who
`have never had to go through it. but it
`costs hundreds of dollars to fill your
`tank with gas,
`if you have a car;
`it
`costs hundreds of dollars to stay at a
`hotel. even if it is just for a day or two:
`it costs hundreds of dollars to drive
`down the road to pick up your elderly
`aunt or your grandmother, who lives in
`another parish, to get her to evacuate.
`I can’t tell you the expense that people
`incur.
`
`PATENT REFORM
`Mr. KYL. Mr. President. I rise today
`to comment on S. 3600, the Patent Re-
`form Act of 2008. This bill is based on,
`but makes a number of changes to, S.
`1145. a patent reform bill that was re—
`ported out of the Judiciary Committee
`in 2007 but that was never considered
`by the full Senate.
`S. 1145 proposed several salutary and
`uncontroversial reforms to the patent
`system, but also included provisions
`that would rewrite the formula for
`awarding damages in patent cases and
`that would create new administrative
`proceedings
`for challenging patents.
`These and other provisions of that bill
`would have made it much more expen-
`sive to hold and defend a patent, would
`have extended the time for recovering
`damages for infringement. and would
`have substantially reduced the amount
`that
`the patent holder would ulti-
`mately recover for infringement. The
`changes proposed by S. 1145 went so far
`that under that bill’s regime, it may
`have proved cheaper in many cases to
`infringe a patent and suffer the attenu-
`ated and reduced consequences of doing
`so, rather than to pay a license to the
`holder of the patent. Once such a line
`is crossed, the incentive to invest in re-
`search and development and the com-
`mercialization of new technology in
`this country would be greatly reduced.
`Such a change would do enormous
`harm to the U.S. economy in the me-
`
`Page 1 of 12
`
`Philips Exhibit 2023
`
`Zoll Lifecor V. Philips
`IPR2013-00609
`
`Philips Exhibit 2023
`Zoll Lifecor v. Philips
`IPR2013-00609
`
`Page 1 of 12
`
`

`

`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`
`S9983
`
`If overly
`awards.
`cessive damages
`broad claim constructions were
`a
`major source of problems with damages
`litigation,
`I undoubtedly would have
`come across at least one neutral expert
`who expressed that View.
`Discussions that I have had with sev-
`eral proponents of S.
`1145 indicated
`that they understand the principal evil
`of current damages litigation to be the
`award of damages as a percentage or
`portion of the full price of the infring-
`ing product. It also appears that some
`proponents of S. 1145 believe that a
`statutory instruction to define the in-
`vention more narrowly and clearly
`would prevent parties from seeking
`damages based on the entire value of
`the infringing product. The linkage be—
`tween claim construction and the dam-
`ages base is not clear to me. Even a
`concededly limited invention could be
`fairly valued by using the full prod—
`uct’s price as the damages base, so long
`as the rate applied to that base was ap—
`propriately small.
`excessive
`and
`Many
`unjustified
`awards certainly do use the full value
`of the infringing product as the dam-
`ages base. Indeed, awards that are de-
`rived from the rule of thumb almost al-
`ways are based on the entire value of
`the infringing product, as is the typical
`industry averages award. Precluding or
`sharply limiting the use of net sales
`price as a damages base certainly
`would block the path to many of the
`bad outcomes that are produced by the
`use of these methodologies.
`The problem with a rule that bars
`the use of net sales price as the dam-
`ages base when calculating a reason-
`able royalty is that in many industrial
`sectors, net sales price is routinely
`used as the damages base in voluntary
`licensing negotiations. It is favored as
`a damages base because it is an objec-
`tive and readily verifiable datum. The
`parties to a licensing negotiation do
`not even argue about its use. Instead,
`they fight over the rate that will be ap-
`plied to that base. Even if the net sales
`price of the product is very large and
`the economic contribution made by the
`patented invention is small, net sales
`price can still serve as the denominator
`of an appropriate royalty if the numer—
`ator is made small.
`Thus in these industries, the initials,
`NSP, appear frequently and repeatedly
`in licensing contracts. A legal rule that
`precluded use of net sales price as the
`damages base would effectively prevent
`participants in these industries from
`making the same royalty calculations
`in litigation that they would make in
`an arm’s length transaction. Such an
`outcome would be deeply disruptive to
`the valuation of patents in these fields.
`Evidence and techniques whose use is
`endorsed by the market via their reg-
`ular use in voluntary negotiations are
`likely to offer the best means of val—
`uing a patent in litigation. After all,
`what is an object in commerce worth,
`other than what the market is willing
`to pay? We simply cannot enact a law
`that bars patentees from using in liti-
`
`gation the same damages calculation
`methods that they routinely employ in
`arm’s length licensing negotiations.
`The bill that I have introduced today
`uses what
`I call an enhanced gate-
`keeper to address problems with dam-
`ages awards. The bill strengthens judi-
`cial
`review of expert witness testi-
`mony, provides greater guidance to ju-
`ries, and allows for sequencing of the
`damages
`and
`validity/infringement
`phases of a trial. The bill also codifies
`the principle that all relevant factors
`can be considered when assessing rea—
`sonable royalty damages, while adopt-
`ing guidelines and rules that favor the
`use of an economic analysis of
`the
`value of an invention over rough or
`subjective methodologies such as the
`rule of thumb,
`industry averages, or
`the use of comparables. Allow me to
`provide
`a
`subsection-by-subsection
`summary of the bill’s revisions to sec-
`tion 284, the basic patent damages stat-
`ute.
`Subsection (a) of the bill’s proposed
`section 284 copies and recodifies all of
`current section 284,
`including its au-
`thorization of treble damages and its
`admonition that compensatory dam-
`ages shall “in no event be less than a
`reasonable royalty for the use made of
`the invention.”
`Subsection (b) codifies current Fed-
`eral circuit precedent defining a rea-
`sonable royalty as the amount that the
`infringer and patent owner would have
`agreed to in a hypothetical negotiation
`at
`the time infringement began. It
`tracks the language of the Rite-Hite
`case, 56 F.3d 1538 (Fed. Cir. 1995), and
`follow-on decisions. Some supporters of
`S. 1145 are critical of the hypothetical
`negotiation construct and believe that
`it leads to bad results. Not only is this
`test established law, however, but it is
`also inherent in the concept of a “rea-
`sonable royalty.” That standard re—
`quires the trier of fact to determine
`what would have been—i.e., what the
`parties would have agreed to. As long
`as the patent code requires a “reason-
`able royalty,” courts and juries will
`need to engage in a hypothetical
`in-
`quiry as to how the invention reason-
`ably would have been valued at the
`time of infringement. Indeed, it is not
`apparent by what other means
`the
`factfinder might approach the calcula-
`tion of a reasonable royalty. And in
`any event, the source of occasional bad
`results in damages trials is not
`the
`mental framework used for approach-
`ing the question of a reasonable roy-
`alty, but rather the particular evidence
`and methods used to value some inven-
`tions. It would be a noteworthy omis-
`sion to avoid mention of the hypo-
`thetical negotiation concept in a bill
`that regulates damages analysis to the
`degree that this one does. This sub-
`section thus codifies the Federal cir-
`cuit’s
`jurisprudence
`on
`the
`hypo-
`thetical negotiation.
`Subsection (0) simply makes clear
`that, despite subsection ((1),
`(e), and
`(f)’s codification and modification of
`several of the Georgia-Pacific factors,
`
`September 27, 2008
`some support in the macro evidence.
`Data
`collected
`by
`PricewaterhouseCoopers and FTI Con-
`sulting indicate that the majority of
`the largest patent-damages awards and
`settlements of all time have been en-
`tered only since 2002. Also, the infla-
`tion adjusted value of awards entered
`since 2000 is more than 50 percent high-
`er than it was during the early 1990s.
`And it also appears that jury awards
`tend to be about ten times higher than
`the average damages award entered by
`a judge, and that results vary mark-
`edly by jurisdiction. These facts sug-
`gest that the problems that sometimes
`lead to inflated damages awards are to
`some extent systemic.
`The task of reforming substantive
`damages standards presents a very dif—
`ficult
`legislative question. Damages
`calculation is an inherently fact-inten-
`sive inquiry and requires legal flexi-
`bility so that the best evidence of a
`patent’s value may always be consid-
`ered. Any proposed changes to the law
`must be evaluated in light of the kalei-
`doscope of factual scenarios presented
`by the calculation of damages for dif-
`ferent types of patents.
`I have largely given up on the idea of
`developing a unified field theory of
`damages law that solves all problems
`at once. I also oppose proposals to re—
`quire a prior—art subtraction in every
`case. Most measures of a reasonable
`royalty, such as established royalties,
`costs of design-arounds, comparisons to
`noninfringing alternatives, or cost sav-
`ings produced by use of the patented
`invention, already effectively deduct
`the value of prior art out of their esti—
`mate of the patented invention’s value.
`To mandate prior-art subtraction when
`using such measures would be to dou-
`ble count that deduction, effectively
`subtracting the prior art
`twice and
`undervaluing the invention.
`And for reasons mostly explained in
`my minority Views to the committee
`report for S. 1145, S. Rep. 110—259 at
`pages 64—65, I also disagree with the ar-
`gument that defendants should be al-
`lowed to revisit validity questions,
`such as a patent’s novelty or non-
`obviousness, during the damages phase
`of
`litigation. To those comments I
`would simply add that,
`if Congress
`were to desire that patents be defined
`more specifically and narrowly, then it
`would need to provide express guidance
`as to how to do so. Simply using adjec-
`tival phrases such as “specific con-
`tribution” or “inventive features” will
`not suffice. These terms merely express
`a hope or objective. But
`legislation
`needs to be about means, not ends, par-
`ticularly if it is intended to achieve its
`results by altering the practices and
`outcomes of litigation.
`I should also
`add that although I have consulted
`with many neutral experts in the field
`of patent damages, and many of those
`experts described to me what they be-
`lieved to be serious problems with pat-
`ent damages litigation, none of those
`experts told me that insufficiently spe-
`cific claim construction is causing ex-
`
`Page 2 of 12
`
`Page 2 of 12
`
`

`

`S9984
`
`the Georgia-Pacific fac—
`the rest of
`tors—as well as any other appropriate
`factor—may be used as appropriate to
`calculate the amount of a reasonable
`royalty.
`Subsection (d) is probably the most
`important subsection in the bill’s re—
`vised section 284. It bars the use of in-
`dustry averages,
`rule-of—thumb profit
`splits, and other standardized measures
`to value a patent except under par-
`ticular
`circumstances. Standardized
`measures are defined as those methods
`that, like rule of thumb and industry
`averages, do not gauge the particular
`benefits and advantages of the use of a
`patent.
`Instead,
`they are relatively
`crude,
`cookie-cutter measures
`that
`purport
`to value all patents—or at
`least all patents in a class—in the same
`way, without regard to a particular
`patent’s economic value. These back—
`of—the envelope methods are occasion-
`ally used in arm‘s-length, voluntary li—
`censing negotiations, as are things
`such as gut instinct and intuition. But
`they are rough methods
`that
`can
`produce wildly inaccurate results. Sub-
`section (d) disfavors their use.
`This subsection restricts the use of
`Georgia-Pacific factor 12, which largely
`describes the rule of thumb. Subsection
`(d)’s general
`rule cites the rule of
`thumb and industry averages as impor-
`tant
`and illustrative
`examples
`of
`standardized measures. But it also ex-
`pressly applies to other methods that
`are “not based on the particular bene—
`fits and advantages” of an invention,
`to ensure that variations on these ex-
`amples and other methods that consist
`of the same evil also are brought with—
`in the scope of subsection (d)’s main
`rule.
`An example of a standardized meas-
`ure other than profit splits and indus-
`try averages that is also currently in
`use and that also falls within sub-
`section (d)’s scope is the so-called IBM
`1-percent—up-to-5
`formula. This
`for-
`mula apparently was used by IBM in
`the past to license its own portfolio of
`patents. Under this methodology, each
`patent receives 1 percent of the reve-
`nues on a product until a 5 percent
`ceiling is reached, at which point the
`whole portfolio of patents is made
`available to the licensee.
`I have heard more than one rep-
`resentative of a high-technology com-
`pany describe the use of this formula in
`litigation against his company. Appar-
`ently, there exists a stable of plaintiff-
`side damages expert witnesses who will
`testify that this formula is appropriate
`for and is customarily used to cal-
`culate the value of any patent in the
`computer or information-technologies
`sectors. These experts start at 1 per-
`cent and then adjust
`that number
`based on the other Georgia—Pacific fac-
`tors, supposedly to account for the par—
`ticular aspects of the patent in suit,
`though these adjustments almost al-
`ways seem to push the number higher.
`Obviously, 1 percent of revenues or
`even profits is a grossly inflated value
`for many high-technology patents. It is
`
`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`September 27, 2008
`found the bill ambiguous on this point,
`not uncommon for high-technology
`and in any event the lack of an excep-
`products to be covered by thousands of
`tion would have forced parties to liti-
`different patents, which are of greatly
`gate the question whether an estab-
`differing value. Not every one of those
`lished royalty was,
`in fact, based on
`patents can be worth 1 percent of reve-
`the benefits and advantages of the use
`nues. Some patents inevitably will be
`for features that are trivial, that are
`of the patent. Since established royal-
`irrelevant to consumers, or that could
`ties are widely considered to be the
`gold standard for valuing a patent, We
`be reproduced by unpatented, off-the-
`should avoid making it harder to use
`shelf noninfringing substitutes. One
`this method. It is thus expressly placed
`percent of the sales revenue from, for
`outside the scope of subsection (d)’s re—
`example, a laptop computer is an enor-
`strictions by paragraph (2).
`mous sum of money. Many patents are
`Paragraph (3) of subsection (d) allows
`worth nothing near
`that, and any
`industry averages to continue to be
`methodology that starts at that num-
`used to confirm that results produced
`ber is likely to produce a grossly in—
`by
`other,
`independently
`allowable
`flated result in a large number of cases.
`methods fall within a reasonable range.
`It bears also mentioning some of
`The paragraph speaks of “independ-
`those
`common methodologies
`that
`ently” allowable methods in order to
`clearly are not standardized measures.
`make clear that an industry average
`In addition to established royalties,
`cannot be used to confirm an estimate
`which are afforded an express exemp-
`produced solely by reference
`to a
`tion from this subsection by paragraph
`“comparable” patent. Subsection (e)
`(2),
`there are the methods of calcu-
`requires that comparables only be used
`lating the costs of designing around a
`in conjunction with or to confirm other
`patent, drawing comparisons to the ex—
`methods,
`and thus under
`this bill
`perience of noninfringing alternatives,
`comparables are not a method whose
`or calculating the costs savings pro—
`use is allowed “independently” of other
`duced by use of the invention. All of
`methods.
`these factors gauge the benefits and ad-
`A brief explanation is in order as to
`vantages of the use of the invention
`why this bill regards industry averages
`and therefore are outside the scope of
`as a potentially unreliable metric and
`subsection ((1).
`restricts their use. An industry average
`Paragraph (1) of subsection ((1) allows
`often will reflect a broad range of li-
`parties to use a standardized measure,
`censing rates within a technological
`such as a rule-of—thumb profit split, if
`sector. Even a licensed patent whose
`that party can show that the patented
`value is included in the calculation of
`invention is the primary reason why
`such a range may fall at a far end of
`consumers buy the infringing product.
`that
`range, producing highly inac—
`If the patented invention is the pri-
`curate results if that average is used as
`mary reason why people buy the prod—
`a starting point
`for calculating the
`uct, then the patent effectively is the
`reason for the commercial success of
`value of that patent. Moreover, many
`existing patents, though valid and in-
`the product, and its owner is entitled
`fringed by a product, disclose trivial
`to a substantial share of the profits,
`inventions that add little to the value
`minus business risk, marketing, and
`of the product. But the types of patents
`other contributions made by the in-
`that typically are licensed—and that
`fringer.
`therefore would be a source of avail—
`Some have advocated a lower stand-
`able data for calculating an industry
`ard than “primary reason” for allowing
`average—are the ones that are substan-
`use of profit splits and other standard-
`tial and valuable. Trivial patents don’t
`ized measures—for example, using a
`“substantial basis” standard. I rejected
`get licensed, and their value does not
`the use of a lower standard because a
`enter into industry average calcula-
`tions. Thus particularly in the case of
`profit split should basically award to
`a minor patent that has never been and
`the patent owner all of the profits on
`likely never would be licensed, an in-
`the product minus those attributable
`to business risk. Thus the test for al-
`dustry average would provide an in-
`flated estimate of the patent’s value.
`lowing such profit splits must be one
`This is because the industry average is
`that only one patent will meet per
`not the average licensing rate of all
`product, since the bulk of the profits
`patents in a field, but merely the aver—
`can only be awarded once. If the test
`were “substantial basis,” for example,
`age of those that have been licensed
`and for which data is publicly avail-
`multiple patents could meet the stand-
`able.
`ard and multiple patent owners could
`Paragraph (4) of subsection (d) cre-
`demand all of the profits minus busi-
`ates a safety valve that allows parties
`ness risk on the product.
`to use standardized measures if no
`Paragraph (2) of subsection (d) makes
`other method is reasonably available
`established royalties an express excep-
`tion to the bar on standardized meas-
`to calculate a reasonable royalty, and
`the standardized method is otherwise
`ures. In earlier drafts, I did not include
`shown to be appropriate for the patent.
`this exception in the bill because I
`Over the course of drafting this bill, I
`thought it obvious that an established
`have consulted with a number of ex-
`royalty is based on the benefits and ad—
`vantages of the use of the invention
`perts with broad experience in patent
`and is thus outside the scope of the
`damages calculation. Only a few be-
`lieved that they had ever seen a case
`subsection (d) rule. Some parties who
`where use of a standardized measure
`reviewed those earlier drafts, however,
`
`Page 3 of 12
`
`Page 3 of 12
`
`

`

`S9985
`
`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`too broad. Parties might define “indus-
`try” so expansively that every patent
`in the universe would fall into one of
`only two or three “industries.”
`Paragraph (2) of subsection (e) sets
`out guideposts for determining whether
`a patent is economically comparable to
`another patent. It suggests requiring a
`showing that the supposed comparable
`is of similar significance to the li-
`censed product as the patent in suit is
`to the infringing product, and that the
`licensed and infringing products have a
`similar profit margin. Obviously, a pat-
`ent that makes only a trivial contribu-
`tion to a product cannot accurately be
`valued by reference to a comparable
`that makes a critical and valuable con-
`tribution to its licensed product, or
`vice versa. And similarity in the profit-
`ability of the licensed and infringing
`products will also generally be impor-
`tant to establishing the economic com-
`parability of two patents. As an eco-
`nomic reality, when the profits on a
`product are high,
`the manufacturer
`will be more generous with the royal-
`ties that he pays for the patented in-
`ventions that are used by the product.
`This economic reality is undergirded
`by the fact that it will typically be the
`patented inventions used by a product
`that make that product unique in the
`marketplace and allow it to earn high-
`er profits. Even if two patents are the
`principal patent on products in the
`same field, if one patent’s product has
`a 2—percent profit margin and the oth—
`er’s has a 20-percent profit margin,
`that first patent evidently is doing less
`to distinguish that product in its mar-
`ket and to generate consumer de-
`mand—and thus has a lower economic
`value.
`com-
`of
`analysis
`thorough
`A
`parability, of course. likely will depend
`in a given case on many factors beyond
`those listed here. Subparagraphs (A)
`and (B) are simply guideposts that de-
`scribe two factors that are likely to be
`relevant
`to comparability. The bill
`only provides that these two factors
`may be considered. It does not preclude
`consideration of other factors, nor does
`it require that these two factors be
`considered in every case. A party as-
`serting the propriety of a comparable
`may be able to show that one or even
`both of these factors are not appro-
`priate to establishing economic com—
`parability in a given case.
`Subsection (f) bars parties from argu-
`ing that damages should be based on
`the wealth or profitability of the de-
`fendant as of the time of trial. Some
`lawyers have been known, after mak-
`ing their case for an inflated royalty
`calculation,
`to emphasize how insig-
`nificant even that inflated request is in
`light of the total revenues of the de-
`fendant infringer. Such arguments do
`not assist the jury in gauging a reason-
`able royalty. Rather, they serve to re-
`duce the jury’s sense of responsibility
`to limit a reasonable royalty to the ac-
`tual value of the use made of the inven-
`tion. This subsection does not bar all
`
`back—of—the-envelope calculation that
`requires only one expert
`to give you
`the industry average licensing rate and
`another to calculate the gross revenues
`on the product. When a complex eco-
`nomic analysis that focuses on non-
`infringing alternatives to the patented
`invention or
`the costs of a design—
`around is forced to compete for the
`jury’s favor with a simple average-rate—
`times-sales calculation, many jurors
`may find the simpler and readily un-
`derstandable method more intuitively
`appealing, even if it is less accurate.
`And of course, when two different and
`even slightly complex damages calcula-
`tions are presented to a jury, there al-
`ways exists a risk that the jury will re-
`solve the dispute by splitting the dif-
`ference between the two methods. In a
`high-value case where the patent owner
`uses an unsound method that produces
`a wildly inflated number, the risk that
`the jury will pick the wrong method or
`even split the difference may easily be
`unacceptable from a business perspec-
`tive.
`In the end, it is the premise of the
`rules of evidence that some types of
`evidence are so unsound, so prejudicial,
`or so likely to produce an unjust result
`that we do not require the other side’s
`lawyer to debunk this evidence, but
`rather we require the judge to bar it
`from the courtroom altogether. If we
`find that particular methodologies rou-
`tinely produce inaccurate and unjust
`results,
`it
`is
`appropriate
`that we
`amend the law to directly restrict the
`use of those methodologies.
`Subsection (e) restricts and regulates
`the use of licenses paid for supposedly
`comparable patents as a means of cal-
`culating the value of the patent in suit.
`The use of comparables is authorized
`by Georgia-Pacific factor two and can
`generate probative evidence of a pat-
`ent’s value. Nevertheless, such use is
`regulated and restricted by this sub—
`section. Comparables are a valuation
`method that is often abused, both to
`overvalue and to undervalue patents.
`When an infringer is sued for infringing
`an important patent, he often will cite
`as evidence of a reasonable royalty the
`license paid for a patent that is in the
`same field but that is much less valu—
`able than the patent in suit. Similarly,
`a plaintiff patent owner asserting a
`trivial patent may cite
`as
`“com-
`parable” other patents in the same
`field that are much more valuable than
`the plaintiff’s patent. The fact that an-
`other patent is licensed in the same in-
`dustry should not alone be enough to
`allow its use as a comparable in litiga-
`tion.
`Comparability is a subjective test.
`By definition, every patent is unique
`and no two patents are truly com-
`parable. Subsection (e)
`thus requires
`that comparables be used only in con-
`junction with or to confirm the results
`of other evidence, and that they only
`be drawn from the same or an analo—
`gous technological
`field.
`I chose the
`latter term rather than “same indus-
`try” because the term “industry” is
`
`September 27, 2008
`was necessary—that is, where a more
`precise economic analysis was not fea-
`sible. I thus anticipate that this safety
`valve may almost never need to be
`used, but I nevertheless include it in
`the bill, because it is impossible to say
`with certainty that no situation will
`ever arise in the future where parties
`will be unable to calculate a reasonable
`royalty without use of
`the rule of
`thumb or other standardized measures.
`Suffice to say that if one party to a
`suit presents appropriate evidence of a
`patent’s value and that evidence falls
`outsi

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket