throbber
ALCON 2022
`Apotex Corp. v. Alcon Research, Ltd.
`Case IPR2013-00428
`
`

`
`
`
`VOL. 85 N0. 2
`
`INFORMATION, EDUCATING, AND MARKETING IN HEALTH CARE
`
`101
`
`traditionally have been relatively unaware
`of drug prices. Other observers have sug-
`gested that moral hazard in the form of
`third-party (insurance) payment practices
`also contributes to low price responsiveness.
`Very little econometric evidence on demand
`elasticities for drugs is available,
`in part
`because the traditional consumer demand
`paradigm (utility maximization, marginal
`rates of
`substitution equal
`to relative
`marginal prices, etc.) cannot be expected to
`describe behavior adequately in a market in
`which principal-agent problems (stemming
`from relationships among physicians, pa-
`tients, and insurers) are widespread.‘ In this
`paper we report elasticity estimates viewed
`from the vantage of the firm, not the “con-
`sumer”—whoever that may be.
`Since marginal production costs are small,
`enhancing revenues is essentially the same
`as increasing profits, and thus drug firms
`face strong incentives to shift out the de-
`mand curves. Thus it is not surprising that
`marketing—sales ratios are quite high in the
`pharmaceutical industry. The largest com-
`ponent
`(70—80 percent) of marketing has
`traditionally involved detailing to physi-
`cians; it consists of a company representa-
`tive providing as much product information
`as possible to physicians, given the typical
`short time of the visit (3-10 minutes) and
`the content regulation enforced by the FDA.
`Medical journal advertising is also carried
`out but is less extensive than detailing. Fi-
`nally, in the last few years, pharmaceutical
`companies have increasingly employed di-
`rect-to-consumer
`advertising in various
`media.
`The information content of marketing ef-
`forts deals primarily with product differen-
`tiation and nonprice aspects.
`In the H2-
`antagonists market,
`five quality attributes
`are of particular importance? First, the var-
`ious H2-antagonists are viewed as being
`roughly similar in efficacy (the four- to six-
`
`;see, however, Michael Baye et al. (1994).
`For more extensive discussion, see Berndt et al.
`(1994).
`.
`
`week treatment healing rate is about 70-80
`percent for duodenal ulcer patients), al-
`though there is some evidence suggesting
`that Zantac has a significantly lower relapse
`rate than does Tagamet for patients on duo-
`denal maintenance treated at recommended
`dosages (see K. R. Gough et al., 1984).
`Second,
`less frequent dosages are thought
`to enhance patient compliance. When Zan-
`tac entered the U.S. market
`in 1983,
`its
`twice-daily dosing frequency was considered
`more favorable than the regimen of four
`times a day recommended for Tagamet.
`Tagamet responded with a twice—a-day ver-
`sion in late 1984, after which considerable
`rivalry ensued; today all four I-I2-antagonists
`have a once—a-day version. A third quality
`attribute involves adverse interactions with
`other drugs. Here Tagamet has been on the
`defensive, for early on it was discovered
`that Tagamet interacted with the liver and
`kidney system in a way that could affect the
`metabolism of other drugs. As of 1994,
`Tagamet had reported to the FDA signifi-
`cant drug interactions with ten other drugs,
`whereas Zantac and Axid had only one re-
`ported drug interaction, and Pepcid had
`none. A fourth quality characteristic in-
`volves side effects. Here again Tagamet has
`been somewhat on the defensive, for condi-
`tions such as mental confusion in the el-
`derly and gynecomastia (breast swelling) for
`males are apparently not as prevalent with
`Zantac, Pepcid, and Axid. Finally, the four
`products compete in terms of medical con-
`ditions (indications) for which the FDA has
`granted treatment
`approval. Although
`Tagamet was the first to win approval for
`the treatment of duodenal ulcers, duodenal
`ulcer maintenance, and gastric ulcers,
`in
`1986 Zantac was the first to obtain approval
`for gastroesophageal
`reflux disease
`(GERD), a rather common condition that
`ranges from modest heartburn and acid in-
`digestion to being a very serious condition.
`The FDA permits marketing only for ap-
`proved indications. Although Tagarnet ob-
`tained FDA approval for GERD in 1991,
`and even though Tagamet had very similar
`effects to Zantac, suggesting that it would
`likely also be effective in treating GERD,
`not having FDA approval
`for GERD
`
`BAN*
`
`and most
`dvertising.
`)I'6 pricing
`and order-
`
`that have
`icture and
`
`industry.
`.
`in particu-
`ict to mar-
`
`ing patent
`nent, per-
`ining final
`g Adminis-
`timated at
`
`er" 4, for
`ucts,
`ng are very
`t data are
`uncommon
`
`percent of
`Informal
`.
`rls suggest
`action costs
`price.
`
`nplications
`:5 firms the
`the extent
`er markup
`humb, one
`-cost condi-
`
`9 = — 1/.99,
`: elasticity.
`-25 percent
`it), the im-
`ould range
`asticities of
`ion percep-
`)1] drugs is
`'emin (1980
`physicians
`
`-...~../.._»-r,m....-\...-«;-..--......i..u.-,i.»--..—V.-.\«-\uw--~'-—-¢-v~rr-r--.-.-im.-m..:-.-...t.n.m.—~..--m-—............_........,....,.....,.._.__...p—-...,._—.i-.......-.--..
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`;-.u...,,m-myuwgr-;.......-...Au--\.-.-...,-i-......--n-fl|A"h-—.,...,....,.,..s.r..,.,-....-M;-.-..-.........w....i_...i
`
`1
`
`
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`I02
`
`AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS
`
`MAY1995
`
`
`EE".'—T-El-E.=l<_/1::arr:
`
`de;
`sin
`tit}
`mi;
`est
`lin.
`
`fol
`Var
`me
`W0
`qua
`cur
`
`LN
`
`
`
`(whereas Zantac did) may have constituted
`a significant marketplace disadvantage for
`Tagamet.
`In terms of pricing, at entry Zantac was
`priced at an 80-percent premium over Taga-
`met, but by May 1994 this premium had
`gradually declined to 19 percent. In May
`1994, the price per day’s treatment (to drug
`stores) was $2.61 for Zantac, $2.56 for Axid,
`$2.30 for Tagarnet, and $2.17 for Pepcid;
`quantity shares for the four products were
`49 percent, 12 percent, 22 percent, and 17
`percent, respectively.
`To understand the roles of marketing,
`pricing, and quality attributes in explaining
`the growth and changing composition of the
`H2-antagonist market, we now outline an
`econometric model
`first
`for
`the H2-
`antagonist industry as a whole, and then for
`the market shares garnered by the four H2-
`antagonist drugs.
`
`I]. An Econometric Model
`
`of the H,-Antagonist Market
`
`At the industry level, we expect the quan-
`tity demanded (number of patient days of
`duodenal-ulcer therapy) to depend on price
`per treatment day, various marketing ef-
`forts, and quality attributes. Since market-
`ing efforts provide long-lived information, it
`is
`important
`that cumulative information
`stocks be distinguished from current-period
`new information flows. Define the cumula-
`tive marketing information stock S, at end
`of month t as
`
`(1)
`
`Sr=(1—5)S:—1+Fr
`I
`
`= X (l—6)TFI—T
`1:0
`
`advertising (DCA)? It is worth noting that
`the DCA efforts for H2-antagonists did not
`mention any drug by name, but only encour-
`aged viewers to seek advice from their
`physician if they experience heartburn and
`acid indigestion.
`Although such DCA advertising is plausi-
`bly intended to augment overall
`industry
`demand, when two or more products exist,
`marketing efforts are often only focused on
`a particular brand. During its monopoly era,
`Tagamet recouped all
`the benefits of its
`marketing efforts (it had 100 percent market
`share).“ However, once Zantac entered,
`even though rivalry between Tagamet and
`Zantac was intense, some of Tagamet’s
`marketing efforts might have spilled over to
`the benefit of Zantac, and vice versa. Simi-
`larly, once Pepcid and Axid entered, while
`marketing efforts were typically focused on
`specific brands, spillovers to Zantac and
`Tagamet might have occurred. To allow for
`marketing spillovers
`affecting industry
`(rather than just product-specific) demand,
`we define the effective industry marketing
`stock Sf‘ as a weighted sum of the market-
`ing information stocks originally formed in
`various market structures:
`
`(2) Sf=F-1S1:+.U«2S2:+l~53S3:+i1vaS4r
`
`is the surviving marketing infor-
`where S,,
`mation stock at end of month t that origi-
`nally accumulated in the Tagamet monopoly
`era, S2,
`is the similar stock formed during
`the Tagamet-Zantac duopoly, S3,
`is that
`from the Tagamet-Zantac-Pepcid triopoly.
`and S4,
`is that from the Tagamet-Zantac
`Pepcid-Axid rivalry. Since in a monopoly all
`marketing efforts affect
`industry demand.
`
`-an--nu
`
`where F, is the flow of new marketing infor-
`mation efforts during month t, and 6 is the
`monthly depreciation rate. Since 6 is un-
`known, we estimate it econometrically. In
`terms of marketing efforts, we distinguish
`three channels: the minutes of detailing to
`physicians (DET), the number of pages of
`medical-journal advertising (PJL), and the
`target rating points of direct-to-consumer
`
`3Target rating points are defined as the target reach
`(the percentage of the over-age-35 population \_'Ji|°
`View the message over the course of the ad camping“
`times the frequency, where frequency is the number
`times the average target individual views the me5SfiE°-
`For further discussion, see Philip Kotler (1991 P9‘
`606-8). The proprietary DCA data were kindly‘ Pf°'
`vided us by Lowe & Partners/SMS in cooperation Will‘
`Glaxo, Inc.
`‘The discussion that follows is based in larsfl 9”"
`on Berndt et al. (1994).
`
`
`
`
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`mm...-...-..—--4--um-i..«m.......W.W.-3--.-.....¢.-....—m...........................,.,,.,,.,_,,,,..,,_,.,___
`
`
`
`
`
`or 1995
`
`noting that
`lists did not
`mly encour-
`from their
`artburn and
`
`rig is plausi-
`all
`industry
`Jducts exist,
`' focused on
`onopoly era,
`nefits of its
`rcent market
`:ac entered,
`‘agamet and
`E Tagamet’s
`ailled over to
`versa. Simi-
`itered, while
`i focused on
`Zantac and
`To allow for
`
`industry
`ng
`fic) demand,
`ry marketing
`? the market-
`
`]:
`
`med in
`
`n + #454:
`
`rketing infor-
`I that origi-
`net monopoly
`)r1ned during
`. S3,
`is
`that
`acid triopoly,
`amet-Zantac-
`
`monopoly all
`stry demand,
`
`; the target reach
`population who
`;he ad campaign)
`is the number of
`ews the message.
`Keller (1991 pp.
`were kindly pro-
`cooperation with
`
`sed in large part
`
`VOL. 85 NO. 2
`
`INFORMATION, EDUCATING, AND MARKETING INHEALTH CARE
`
`103
`
`we normalize the ,u’s by setting it, = 1.
`Several interesting hypotheses involve the
`p,’s. First, if the effectiveness of firms’ mar-
`keting on industry sales is independent of
`market structure,
`then pi, = p.3 == p., = 1.
`Second,
`if in the presence of competition
`_marketing efforts only affect market shares
`and have a zero—sum impact on industry
`_demand, then 11.2 = in, = ,u,, = 0. Finally,
`if
`the industry sales—augmenting effects of
`firms’ marketing decline as the number of
`products in the industry increases, then 1 >
`u2>#«3>u«4>0-
`'- For our industry demand equation, we
`specify a log-log model, where Q,
`is quan-
`tity, P,
`is CPI-deflated price, DET,*, PJLT,
`and DCA"j are the effective industry stocks
`defined in (1) and (2), and DGERD is a
`dummy variable taking on the value of 1
`following FDA approval for GERD:
`
`pages marketing stocks, LNDTJ1 and
`LNJPJ 1; the number of adverse drug inter-
`actions for product j relative to Tagamet,
`I_.NINTIl;5 a discrete variable, DSGERD,
`indicating whether product j has a GERD
`indication advantage relative to Tagamet (1,
`advantage; 0, no advantage; -1, disadvan-
`tage); an order-of-entry variable, ENTRY,
`taking on the value of 2 for all Zantac
`observations, 3 for Pepcid, and 4 for Axid;
`and an AGE variable indicating the number
`of months product j has been in the mar-
`ketplace. Again, an instrumental-variable
`procedure is employed to allow for simul-
`taneity.
`Our data sources are described more fully
`in Berndt et al. (1994).? The direct-to-com
`sumer marketing data are for a campaign
`begun by Glaxo (the manufacturer of Zan-
`tac) in June 1992., and they extend through
`May 1994.
`
`(3) LNQ, = ,3, + ,B,LNP, + [32LNDET,*
`
`III. Econometric Results
`
`+ ;3,LN1=JL=*; + ,B,,LNDCA’j
`
`+ B5DGERD, + 3,.
`
`Since the effective industry marketing stocks
`depend nonlinearly on the ,u’s and 8’s, and
`since marketing efforts, pricing, and quan-
`tity demanded are likely to be jointly deter-
`1 mined (see Richard Schmalensee 1972), we
`estimate parameters in equation (3) by non-
`linear two—stage least squares (NL—2SLS).5
`Our econometric model of market shares
`follows Urban et al.
`(1986)
`in specifying
`variables relative to the incumbent (Taga-
`_ met). In particular, using a log-log frame-
`work, we specify that in month I, demand
`"quantities of product
`1' relative to the in-
`cumbent [ln(Q,-/Q,)E LNQ.Il, j= Zantac,
`Pepcid, Axid] depend on:
`relative prices,
`LNPRJ1;
`relative detailing and journal-
`
`SA5 instruments, we employ the producer price in-
`dex for intermediate goods, production worker wages
`in the pharmaceutical industry, cumulative marketing
`(“TONS by the four companies on non-H2-antagonist
`-' Products for each of the three instruments, and time.
`
`Based on 201 monthly observations from
`September 1977 through May 1994, we esti-
`mated parameters of equation (3) for the
`industry using NL-2SLS. To be parsimo-
`nious in parameters, we constrained the ,u.’s
`and 6’s to be the same for the DET and
`PJL marketing stocks, but allowed 8 to dif-
`fer for DCA. The preferred model was cho-
`sen based on the lowest value of the tradi-
`tional NL—2SLS residual criterion function.
`Our estimated H2-antagonist
`industry
`price elasticity is -0.689 (1 =3.80), while
`elasticity estimates for the DET, PJL, and
`DCA surviving stocks are 0.553 (I = 7.52),
`0.198 (I = 2.79) and 0.008 (t = 2.67).“ Hence,
`industry demand is positively affected by all
`three of the firms’ marketing channels, but
`D131" is most effective; the sum of the three
`marketing elasticities is 0.759, suggesting
`decreasing returns to scale.
`In terms of
`
`E'To accommodate zeros, 1.0 is added to both the
`DCA and the [NT variables.
`7Here we extend the Berndt et al. (1994) data base
`to May 1994. Data on prices, quantities, detailing, and
`journal pages are from IMS International.
`8The equation R2 is 0.995, and the Durbin-Watson
`statistic is 1.912.
`
`
`
`

`
`104
`
`AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS
`
`MAY 1995
`
`,u.3, and 1.1.4
`spillovers, the estimates of ,u.2,
`are 0.601 (t=6.59), 0.924 (t=5.30), and
`0.410 (t = 4.00); these ,u.’s are jointly signif-
`icantly different from 1, and from zero, indi-
`cating that marketing spillovers occur and
`that
`the effectiveness of- firms’ marketing
`efforts on industry sales depends on market
`structure. The extent
`to whichspillovers
`occur, however, does not decline monotoni-
`cally with the number of products in the
`_market. The DGERD dummy variable co-
`efficient
`is 0.104 (t -= 3.20), indicating that
`FDA approval for GERD increased the size
`of the H2-antagonist market by about 10
`percent. Finally,
`the NL-ZSLS criterion
`function is optimized at the point where 8
`for the DET and PJL stocks is 0.00, while
`that for the DCA stock is 0.15 (t =0.20),
`implying an annual DCA deterioration rate
`of about 80 percent. Although we are some-
`what surprised that the information stocks
`of DCA and PJL marketing do not depreci-
`ate at all, we note that a similar 5=0
`finding in the context of R&D knowledge
`stocks has been reported by Zvi Griliches
`and Frank Lichtenberg (1984).
`Turning now to econometric results based
`on the market-share model, we obtained the
`following NL-ZSLS results, based on 291
`monthly observations:
`
`LNQJ1, = -0.4-27ENTRY — 0.057 LNPRJ1,
`(44.00)
`(3.95)
`
`+ 0.649LNDT.l1,+ 0.167LNJPJ1
`(19.77)
`(6.31)
`
`+ 0.052 DSGERD, — 0.252 LNINTJ1
`(2.17)
`(9.00)
`
`+
`
`0.010AGE
`(10.05)
`
`with an R2 of 0.983. Order-of-entry effects
`are negative and strong, implying significant
`first-mover advantages, consistent with evi-
`dence from other markets (see Urban et al.,
`1986). The within-H2-antagonist price-elas-
`ticity estimate is ~ 0.67 and significant, while
`coefficients on relative stocks of detailing
`(0.649) and journal pages of advertising
`(0.167) are positive and significant. The esti-
`
`mated monthly depreciation rate for the
`DET and PJL stocks is 0.030 (I =13.77),
`implying that relative information market-
`ing stocks deteriorate at about 30 percent
`per year. With respect to quality variables,
`the DSGERD coeflicient is 0.05, while that
`on relative adverse drug interactions is
`-0.25, suggesting that Tagamet’s market
`share was significantly negatively affected by
`its disadvantages in terms of GERD and
`adverse drug interactions
`in the H 2-
`antagonist market. Finally,
`the age coeffi-
`cient
`is positive and significant,
`implying
`that, ceteris paribus, longevity in the mar-
`ketplace positively affects market shares.”
`
`IV. Concluding Remarks
`
`We have reported results on factors af-
`fecting the growth and composition of the
`H2-antagonist drug market. With an H,
`antagonist
`industry own-price elasticity of
`-0.69 and between-drug price elasticities
`of -0.66,
`the implicit brand—specific own-
`price elasticities in May 1994 are -0.80 for
`Tagamet (SE = 0.08), - 1.03 (SE = 0.12) for
`Zantac, -0.76 (SE = 0.08) for Pepcid, and
`-0.74 (SE = 0.08)
`for Axid. Except
`for
`Zantac,
`these elasticity estimates are still
`slightly smaller than the - 1.1 to - 1.3 val-
`ues one might expect based on the Lerner
`markup rule of thumb; nevertheless they
`are not far from 1, and clearly differ from 0.
`It is worth noting that when marketing vari-
`ables are omitted from the relative—demand
`equations, price-elasticity estimates fall
`to
`about half these values.
`We find that marketing information stocks
`positively affect sales, that the sales ClE15llC-
`ity is largest for detailing, followed by jour-
`nal pages of advertising, and is smallest _f0f
`direct-to—consumer advertising. Marketing
`information appears to display overall dt3'
`creasing returns to scale. We also find Illa‘
`
`9AIthough DCA is arguably intended to aflecl
`tn‘ demand rather than market shares, when th€ Dcd
`information variable is added, shares of Tagalne‘ “'1
`Axid were Positively affected relative to those Of 13""
`tat: and Pepcid.
`
`

`
`
`
`VOL. 85 NO. 2
`
`order-of—entry effects are significant, as are
`quality attributes.
`
`REFERENCES
`
`105
`INFORMATION, EDUCATING, AND MARKETING IN HEALTH CARE
`Lancet, 22 September 1984, 2(8404), pp.
`659-62.
`Griliches, Zvi and Lichtenberg, Frank. “R&D
`and Productivity Growth at the Industry
`Level: Is There Still a Relationship?” in
`Zvi Griliches, ed., R&D, patents, and pro-
`ductivity. Chicago: University of Chicago
`Press, 1984, pp. 465-502.
`Kotler, Philip. Marketing Management, 7th
`Ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall,
`1991.
`Schmalensee, Richard L. The economics of ad-
`vertising. Amsterdam: North-Holland,
`1972.
`Temin, Peter. Taking your medicine: Drug reg-
`ulation in the United States. Cambridge,
`MA: Harvard University Press, 1980.
`Urban, Glen L.; Carter, Theresa; Gaskin, Steve
`and Mucha, Zofia. “Market Share Rewards
`to Pioneering Brands: An Empiricai
`Analysis
`and Strategic
`Implications.”
`Management Science, June 1986, 32(6),
`pp. 645-59.
`
`'Baye, Michael R.; Mnness, Robert and Wiggins,
`Steven N. “Demand Systems and the ‘True’
`Cost of Living for Pharmaceuticals.”
`Working paper, Department of Eco-
`nomics, Texas A&M University, May
`1994.
`Berndt, Ernst R.; Bui, Linda; Reiley, David and
`' Urban, Glen. “The Roles of Marketing,
`Product Quality and Price Competition in
`
`' Anti-Ulcer Drug Industry.” National Bu-
`reau of Economic Research (Cambridge,
`-MA) Working Paper No. 4904, October
`1994.
`_Gough, K. R.; Korman, M. G.; Bardhan, K. D.;
`Lee, F. L; Crowe, J. P.; Reed, P. I. and Smith,
`R. N. “Ranitidine and Cimetidine in Pre-
`vention of Duodenal Ulcer Relapse.” The
`
`MAY 1995
`
`ate for the
`
`' (t =13.T’),
`zion market-
`t 30 percent
`ity variables,
`5, while that
`:eractions is
`net’s market
`iy affected by
`GERD and
`
`the H2.
`in
`e age coeffi-
`mt,
`implying
`in the mar-
`;et shares?
`
`rks
`
`lfl factors af-
`rsition of the
`
`With an H2-
`elasticity of
`:e elasticities
`-specific own-
`ir’
`0.80 for
`31
`1.12) for
`r Pepcid, and
`. Except
`for
`rates are still
`. to -1.3 val-
`)n the Lerner
`zrtheless they
`differ from 0.
`iarketing vari-
`lative-demand
`imates fall
`to
`
`rmation stocks
`5: sales elastic-
`lowed by jour-
`is smallest for
`1g. Marketing
`ay overall de-
`. also find that
`
`led to affect indus—
`es, when the DCA
`:5 of Tagarnet and
`e to those of Zan-
`
`
`
`.......i.i.,,..
`
`i i

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket