throbber
3%
`
`fix
`
`:?"’i.F'J_ ~«s_.. V
`
`3-;
`
`ContentGuard Exhibit 2004
`
`TZTE v. ContentGuard
`IPR2013-00133
`
`ContentGuard Exhibit 2004
`ZTE v. ContentGuard
`IPR2013-00137
`
`

`
`Internet Dreams
`
`Archetypes, Myths, and Metaphors
`
`Mark Stefik
`
`The MIT Press
`
`Cambridge, Massachusetts
`London, England
`
`u3
`
`"w»s-
`‘V
`’
`'1
`,9.»-?a“§”‘e;.e~ W
`
`

`
`Third printing, 2001
`© 1996 Massachusetts Institute of Technology
`
`All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any
`electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or informa-
`tion storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher.
`
`This book was set in Sabon by Asco Trade Typesetting Ltd., Hong Kong and was
`printed and bound in the United States of America.
`
`Images of the metaphors are by Eric P. Stefik.
`
`Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
`
`Internet dreams : archetypes, myths, and metaphors /Mark Stefik.
`p.
`cm.
`) and index.
`Includes bibliographical references (p.
`ISBN 0-262-19373-6 (HB), O-262-69202-3 (PB)
`1. Information superhighway-~United States. 2. Internet (Computer
`network)—United States. I. Stefik, Mark.
`ZA3250.U6I58
`1996
`303.48'33—dc2O
`
`96-28249
`CIP
`
`

`
`Contents
`
`Foreword by Vinton C. Cerf
`
`1x
`
`Acknowledgments
`Introduction
`x111
`
`x1
`
`Part 1: The Digital Library Metaphor: The I—Way as Publishing and
`Community Memory
`1
`
`Excerpt from “As We May Think”
`Vannevar Bush
`
`15
`
`Excerpt from Libraries of the Future
`
`23
`
`J. C. R. Licklider
`
`Excerpt from The Digital Library Project, volume 1:
`
`33
`The World of Knou/bots
`Robert E. Kahn and Vinton G. Cerf
`
`Excerpt from “Communication as the Root of Scientific Progress”
`Joshua Lederberg
`
`39
`
`Excerpt from “What Is the Role of Libraries in the Information
`Economy?”
`55
`
`John Browning
`
`Technological Revolutions and the Gutenberg Myth
`Scott D. N. Cook
`
`67
`
`Excerpt from “Libraries Are More than Information: Situational Aspects
`of Electronic Libraries”
`83
`
`Vicky Reich and Mark Weiser
`
`

`
`vi
`
`Contents
`
`Excerpt from “The Electronic Capture and Dissemination of the Cultural
`Practice of Tibetan Thangka Painting”
`95
`
`Ranjit Makkuni
`
`Part 2: The Electronic Mail Metaphor: The I~Way As a
`Communications Medium 109
`
`Some Consequences of Electronic Groups
`Lee Sproull and Samer Faraj
`
`125
`
`135
`
`Netiquette 101
`Jay Machado
`Excerpt from “The MPC Adventures: Experiences with the Generation
`of VLSI Design and Implementation Methodologies”
`143
`
`Lynn Conway
`Excerpt from “Digital Communications and the Conduct of Science:
`The New Literacy”
`161
`
`Joshua Lederberg
`Part 3: The Electronic Marketplace Metaphor: Selling Goods and
`Services on the I-Way
`173
`
`Excerpt from “Electronic Commerce on the Internet”
`From the CommerceNet Home Page
`
`187
`
`Excerpt from “Electronic Markets and Electronic Hierarchies”
`Thomas W. Malone, Joanne Yates, and Robert 1. Benjamin
`
`Slaves of a New Machine: Exploring the For-Free/For~Pay
`Conundrum 207
`
`Laura Fillmore
`
`Letting Loose the Light: Igniting Commerce in Electronic
`Publication
`219
`
`Mark Stefik
`
`Part 4: The Digital Worlds Metaphor: The I-Way As a Gateway to
`Experience
`255
`Excerpt from “Mudding: Social Phenomena in Text-Based Virtual
`Realities”
`265
`
`Pavel Curtis
`
`

`
`Contents
`
`vii
`
`A Rape in Cyberspace: How an Evil Clown, a Haitian Trikster Spirit,
`Two Wizards, and a Cast of Dozens Turned a Database into a
`
`Society
`
`293
`
`Julian Dibbell
`
`Interaction Without Society?. What Avatars Can’t Do
`
`317
`
`Harry M. Collins
`
`Excerpt from “Toward Portable Ideas”
`Mark Stefik and John Seely Brown
`
`327
`
`The National Collaboratory—A White Paper
`William A. Wulf
`
`345
`
`Internet Dreams: First Encounters of an On-line Dream Group
`
`353
`
`Barbara Viglizzo
`
`Epilogue: Choices and Dreams
`
`389
`
`Further Reading
`Sources
`401
`
`399
`
`Contributors
`Index
`407
`
`403
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Mark Stefik
`
`Connections
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`In “The Digital Library Project: The World of Knowbots” in Part 1,
`Robert Kahn and Vinton Cerf ask, “If a thousand books are combined
`on a single CD-ROM and the acquirer of the CD-ROM only intends
`to read one of them, what sort of royalty arrangement is appropriate
`to compensate the copyright owners? How would compensation be
`extended for cases in which electronic copies are provided to users?”
`Their questions show how, in 1988, issues about copyright protection
`and payment for using information arose in the context of early CD-
`ROM distribution.
`they were
`By 1994 copyright issues not only had not been settled,
`coming to a boil. Laura Fillmore’s effort to build a successful publishing
`business on the Internet reveals the limitations of what was practical in
`May of 1994. Although digital works were being sold on the Internet,
`provisions for commerce were primitive. Furthermore, the ease of copy-
`ing digital works had led many people to believe that digital information
`should be free. Fast access to the network had made trading programs or
`other data as easy as mixing songs on audio tape. In short, it had become
`much simpler for network users to infringe copyright’ than to uphold it.
`This is the context for the oft—quoted statement by john Perry Barlow
`of the Electronic Freedom Foundation, “Copyright is dead.” Advocates
`of free information argue that because you don’t lose the original when
`you make a copy of a digital work, there should be no charge for copying
`information. The conventional wisdom among publishers in late—1994,
`when this article was written, was that digital containers for software
`
`
`
`

`
`220
`
`Mark Stefile
`
`were inherently leaky vessels and that no viable solution would ever be
`found. The article suggests, however, a way to sustain commerce for
`those who want to sell information on the network.
`
`Throughout the time I’ve been groping around cyberspace, an immense, unsolved
`conundrum has remained at the root of nearly every legal, ethical, governmental,
`and social vexation to be found in the Virtual World. I refer to the problem of
`digitized property. The enigma is this: If our property can be infinitely reproduced
`and instantaneously distributed all over the planet without cost, without our
`knowledge, without its even leaving our possession, how can we protect it? How
`are we going to get paid for the work we do with our minds? And, if we can’t get
`paid, what will assure the continued creation and distribution of such work?
`John Perry Barlow, “The Economy of Ideas”
`
`No problemo.
`T-101 (Arnold Schwarzenegger) in Terminator 2
`It all depends on whether you really understand the idea of trusted systems. If you
`don’t understand them, then this whole approach to commerce and digital pub-
`lishing is utterly unthinkable. If you do understand them, then it all follows
`easily.
`
`Ralph Merkle
`
`Across many cultures, knowledge and inner knowing are described as
`light. Letting loose the light refers to spreading knowledge in the world,
`typically in written form. Consistent with this metaphor, the period in
`the eighteenth century characterized by a burst of writings in philosophy
`and science is called the Enlightenment. In the present century the meta-
`phor of knowledge as light is both poetic and physically realized. Books,
`pictures, movies, musical performances, and other works can be con—
`veniently represented digitally. With fiber optics, digital works are actually
`transmitted by the shining and pulsing of light.
`The digital representation of works and their nearly instantaneous
`transmission has profound consequences for commercial publishing.
`Three of the fundamental economic factors affecting the publishing
`industry——printing costs, inventory costs, and transportation costs——Ca1’1
`be drastically reduced. Digital works can be copied at minuscule costs,
`stored in almost no space, and transported instantly anywhere in the
`world.
`
`

`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`machine. In the technophile’s idealized vision, books and magazines need
`never be printed on paper at all; any digital work could be made avail-
`
`able to anyone, anytime, anywhere in the world.
`
`However, the dream of universal digital access to high-quality works
`dangles just beyond reach. Such works are not usually available, because
`of publishers’ concerns that uncompensated copying will infringe and
`erode their ability to make a living. History suggests that this problem
`will not go away. Publishing thrives only when it is profitable, and prof-
`itability depends on limiting uncompensated copying.
`
`The conventional wisdom—based on the way computers are used
`for word processing, electronic mail, and computer networking—is that
`copying digital works is easy and, therefore, inevitable. There appears to
`be a clear, inherent conflict between representing works digitally and
`honoring the commercial and intellectual property interests of creators
`
`and publishers. Fortunately, computers need not be blind instruments of
`
`copyright infringement. Properly designed digital systems can be more
`
`powerful and flexible instruments of trade in publications than any other
`
`medium. The seeming conflict between digital publishing and commerce
`
`is merely a consequence of the way computer systems have been designed
`to date.
`
`The technological means for commerce in digital works are now at
`
`hand. New and unconventional when compared with today’s uses of
`
`computers, these means will enable us to buy, sell, and lend digital works
`
`much as we now buy, sell, and lend printed books and other pub—
`
`lications. They will change the way digital works are purchased and
`
`delivered and will give consumers access to all sorts of works at any time
`
`of the day——though not necessarily for free. Consumers will be able to
`
`sample works, borrow them, rent them for nominal fees, and make
`
`copies for friends. Creative people will be able to circulate their works to
`
`networks of friends while earning a reliable living from people who make
`copies of them. This technological system will affect everything from
`digital books to digital
`television, from digital music to digital video
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`

`
`222
`
`Mark Stefik
`
`games. It will radically change our concepts of digital libraries, digital
`bookstores, digital music stores, digital newspapers, and digital television
`stations. Moreover, any competent technological company will be able to
`implement the required systems.
`Here is a road map to this new land. First, we discuss the history of
`copyright law and the reasons for the widespread, but incorrect, belief
`that works represented digitally will be copied without permission. We
`then describe the technological innovations that can enable and support
`commerce in digital publishing. Finally, we introduce the institutional
`and business challenges that lie ahead. What we require to overcome
`them is the wit, will, and means to create institutions that provide the
`necessary security, convenience, vision, and longevity.
`
`The Origin and Rationale of Copyright
`
`It is harder to be honest than to cheat when copying digital works on
`general-purpose computers. The license printed on the package of most
`purchased computer software authorizes a buyer to load the software
`into one computer and use it there. Getting another legal copy for a
`friend involves driving to the computer store and buying it. It is much
`easier, faster, and cheaper to simply load the same software into another
`computer. Such copying is so private and easy to do that most people do
`. it without thinking, and without guilt.
`Unauthorized copying on computers is not, of course, limited to pur-
`chased software. With a few keystrokes, it is often possible to copy a
`paragraph, an article, a book, or a life’s work without compensating its
`creators or publishers. Nor are unauthorized copying and use new phe-
`nomena. Anyone who ignores the FBI warning message on video tapes to
`make copies for friends infringes a copyright, as do people who copy
`compact discs onto cassettes. As a practical matter, it has not been fea-
`sible to enforce the copyright law in these cases. There are simply too
`many people with recording devices to make rigorous enforcement prac-
`tical or cost—effective.
`It is widely believed that there_is no viable technical solution to this
`problem for digital information. John Perry Barlow, a prominent spokes-
`person in the computer industry, says that the idea of patents and copy-
`
`

`
`tried at least once, and it didn’t work. Apparently, for high-quality works
`to spread in the world people need to be able to make a living from
`creating and distributing them.
`’
`Barlow’s arguments are reminiscent of the intense debates about intel-
`lectual property that took place in France during the French Revolution.
`Like Barlow, revolutionaries argued that ideas cannot be owned and
`should not be regulated. During the revolution, many writers and under-
`ground publishers emerged as civic heroes of public enlightenment by
`arguing against tyranny and for freedom of the press. The revolution of
`the mind, they said, required the dismantling of the laws and institutions
`governing authorship, printing, publishing, and bookselling. Absolutely
`free communication was one of the most precious rights of man. All
`citizens should be able to speak, to write, and crucially, to print freely.
`According to this philosophical ideal, people had a will to know and
`should be allowed to read and learn from anything they liked. The wide
`availability of books and the right to publish were seen as keys to this
`spread of knowledge.
`In 1789, the revolutionary government wholly deregulated the press,
`believing that the works of the great writers of the Enlightenment would
`thus be made universally and cheaply, available. The writers and pub~
`lishers certainly never expected what actually happened. Instead of works
`of enlightenment, the presses turned out mostly seditious pamphlets and
`pornography. Printers also competed with each other to bring out cheap
`editions of books others had spent money developing. So little money
`could be made producing the good books that quality declined; most
`editions were abridged and contained many errors. Publisher after pub-
`lisher went into bankruptcy and then out of business. The disastrous
`nature of an unregulated press, largely unanticipated in the heat of the
`revolution, became blatantly obvious as the publishing industry fell into
`shambles. The same leaders who had clamored for the freeing of the
`presses came belatedly to understand the folly of their action. In the
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`

`
`224
`
`Mark Stefilz
`
`chaos of the unregulated press, some prominent and popular writers even
`stopped publishing; because they could not control the printing of their
`works, they could not make a living by writing.
`In 1793 legislation to restore order to publishing was passed. It rec-
`ognized the rights of authors and grounded the publishing industry in
`the principles of the marketplace, establishing the author as creator,
`the book as property, and the reader as an elective consumer. This law
`reflected a fundamental shift in the Enlightenment perspective, which
`now saw that the widespread creation and publication of creative works
`was better served when the authors could own the products of their
`minds. This history of the treatment of intellectual property in France is
`discussed by Carla Hesse in her book Publishing and Cultural Politics in
`Revolutionary Paris, 1789-1810.
`
`Today, most people see the infringement of copyright on digital systems
`as unavoidable. In the remainder of this section, we describe the assump-
`tions about computer design behind this belief and argue that we need to
`go beyond conventional ways of thinking to solve the problem.
`Three main factors currently inhibit the development of digital pub-
`lishing:
`(1) the absence of high-contrast,
`low—power, cheap flat-panel
`displays; (2) lack of an inexpensive and reliable way of handling money
`digitally; and (3) the need for a widely accepted means of accounting for
`the use and copying of digital works. Improvements in technology will
`almost certainly solve the display problem in the next five to ten years.
`Most people see such displays as crucial to making electronic books
`and newspapers portable. They matter less, however, in applications for
`which desktop displays are satisfactory or where displays are not neces-
`sary-—such as in transmitting musical works. The second factor~meth—
`ods of handling money digitally, in the form of checks, credit cards, or
`anonymous cas
`imentation. Our focus is on the third problem, techniques for commerce
`in what we call digital property rights or usage rights, a generalization
`of the idea of copyright that delineates several kinds of rights besides
`copying.
`Some publishers see illicit copying as too big a business risk and do not
`publish in digital form at all. Digital newspapers often leave out impor-
`
`

`
`computer software, have found that some leakage increases their cus-
`tomer base, even though it is often reported that there are more unau-
`thorized copies of a program in use than authorized ones. Software
`publishers have decided that the revenue losses of illegal copying are
`affordable, although they lead to unfair billing. Software publishers
`charge all users the same price, regardless of the use to which they put the
`program, arguably overbilling people who use the work infrequently.
`As computers and computer networks have proliferated, the need for a
`better approach to protecting digital works has become more widely
`appreciated. Moreover, as new kinds of works——such as music, video,
`and multimedia works that mix these forms—are now available digitally,
`people from different industries are searching for solutions. Given this
`wide acknowledgment of the need, why have solutions seemed so elu-
`sive? Apparently, we are stuck in a rut, assuming that things must be
`done the way they have always been done with electronic mail, word
`processing, and other current applications.
`Conventionally, we use general-purpose computers with general-
`purpose operating systems and general-purpose programs. The computer
`industry, grounded on the premise that computers can do anything that
`can be programmed in software, produces a wide range of programs—-
`word processors, spreadsheets, databases, calendars, graphics programs,
`and computer games. Manufacturers accept no liability when someone
`uses a computer to copy a copyrighted file. After all, one company builds
`the computer, another writes the software that does the copying, and
`both hardware and software are intended for general purposes——that is,
`any purpose the user wants to put them to. The manufacturer wants no
`responsibility for someone who uses the computer in a way that just
`happens to infringe a copyright, nor does the software publisher. The
`perpetrator is the consumer, who finds it easier to make an unauthorized
`copy than to be strictly honest.
`
`

`
`226
`
`Mark Stefik
`
`Stuck within this framework the community of computer users pro-
`tests against any attempt to regulate the copying of digital property. If we
`continue to accept this framework, with all of its assumptions, no party
`will be motivated or empowered to break the cycle and no effective
`way to protect digital property will be developed. At present, without
`enforceable property rights, the writers of words, interactive games, and
`songs often are not compensated for their work. And without their
`works the world is a darker, poorer place. Honoring their creative work
`in the digital systems of tomorrow requires us to challenge the design
`assumptions of the systems we use today.
`
`A New Design for Digital Publishing
`
`The technical core of the approach we propose is based on two ideas: (1)
`that digital works can be bought and sold among trusted systems, and (2)
`that works have attached usage rights that specify what can be done with
`them and what it costs to exercise those rights.
`
`Trusted Systems
`The term trusted system refers to computers that can be relied on to do
`certain things. For example, suppose that a creator or publisher forbids
`all copying of a particular digital work. A trusted system in this context
`would reliably and infallibly carry out that stipulation; no amount of
`shouting or coaxing would coerce it to copy the work. The trusted sys-
`tem might be very polite, but ultimately it would always refuse to make
`an unauthorized copy. Similarly, suppose that a trusted system could
`copy a work but only if it reliably records a set fee to be paid when it has
`done so. A trusted system would always record the fee whenever the
`work was copied. If the copying process is interrupted part way through,
`the trusted system would follow a standard policy; for example, it might
`delete the partial copy, record no fee, and note that a copying attempt
`was begun but not completed. Again, no amount of coaxing would
`change its behavior. It could always be counted on to follow the rules of
`
`the trust.
`A common but false analogy claiming to show why digital works
`cannot be protected in computers is that of genies and bottles. In this

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket