throbber
AVAYA INC. AV-1022
`Avaya Inc. v. Network-1 Security Solutions, Inc.
`IPR2013-00071
`
`

`

`S9983
`
`September 27, 2008
`some support
`in the macro evidence.
`Data
`collected
`by
`PricewaterhouseCoopers and FTI Con—
`sulting indicate that the majority of
`the largest patent-damages awards and
`settlements of all time have been en-
`tered only since 2002. Also,
`the infla—
`tion adjusted value of awards entered
`since 2000 is more than 50 percent high—
`er than it was during the early 19905.
`And it also appears that jury awards
`tend to be about ten times higher than
`the average damages award entered by
`a judge, and that results vary mark—
`edly by jurisdiction. These facts sug-
`gest that the problems that sometimes
`lead to inflated damages awards are to
`some extent systemic.
`The task of reforming substantive
`damages standards presents a very dif—
`ficult
`legislative question. Damages
`calculation is an inherently fact-inten—
`sive inquiry and requires legal flexi-
`bility so that the best evidence of a
`patent‘s value may always be consid-
`ered. Any proposed changes to the law
`must be evaluated in light of the kalei—
`doscope of factual scenarios presented
`by the calculation of damages for dif—
`ferent types of patents.
`I have largely given up on the idea of
`developing a unified field theory of
`damages law that solves all problems
`at once. I also oppose proposals to re-
`quire a prior-art subtraction in every
`case. Most measures of a reasonable
`royalty, such as established royalties,
`costs of design—arounds. comparisons to
`noninfringing alternatives, or cost sav—
`ings produced by use of the patented
`invention. already effectively deduct
`the value of prior art out of their esti—
`mate of the patented invention‘s value.
`To mandate prior-art subtraction when
`using such measures would be to dou—
`ble count that deduction, effectively
`subtracting the prior art
`twice and
`undervaluing the invention.
`And for reasons mostly explained in
`my minority views to the committee
`report for S. 1145, S. Rep. 110—259 at
`pages 64455, I also disagree with the ar—
`gument that defendants should be al-
`lowed to revisit validity questions,
`such as a patent‘s novelty or non-
`obviousness, during the damages phase
`of
`litigation. To those comments I
`would simply add that.
`if Congress
`were to desire that patents be defined
`more specifically and narrowly, then it
`would need to provide express guidance
`as to how to do so. Simply using adjec-
`tival phrases such as “specific con-
`tribution" or “inventive features” will
`not suffice. These terms merely express
`a hope or objective. But
`legislation
`needs to be about means, not ends. par—
`ticularly if it is intended to achieve its
`results by altering the practices and
`outcomes of litigation.
`I should also
`add that although I have consulted
`with many neutral experts in the field
`of patent damages, and many of those
`experts described to me what they be-
`lieved to be serious problems with pat—
`ent damages litigation, none of those
`experts told me that insufficiently spe—
`cific claim construction is causing ex—
`
`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`gation the same damages calculation
`cessive damages
`awards.
`If overly
`broad claim constructions were
`a
`methods that they routinely employ in
`arm‘s length licensing negotiations.
`major source of problems with damages
`The bill that I have introduced today
`litigation,
`I undoubtedly would have
`uses what
`I call an enhanced gate-
`come across at least one neutral expert
`keeper to address problems with dam-
`who expressed that view.
`Discussions that I have had with sev-
`ages awards. The bill strengthens judi-
`cial
`review of expert witness testi-
`eral proponents of S.
`1145 indicated
`mony, provides greater guidance to ju-
`that they understand the principal evil
`ries, and allows for sequencing of the
`of current damages litigation to be the
`damages
`and
`validity/infringement
`award of damages as a percentage or
`phases of a trial. The bill also codifies
`portion of the full price of the infring—
`the principle that all relevant factors
`ing product. It also appears that some
`can be considered when assessing rea-
`proponents of S. 1145 believe that a
`sonable royalty damages. while adopt—
`statutory instruction to define the in—
`ing guidelines and rules that favor the
`vention more narrowly and clearly
`use of an economic analysis of
`the
`would prevent parties from seeking
`value of an invention over rough or
`damages based on the entire value of
`subjective methodologies such as the
`the infringing product. The linkage be-
`rule of thumb,
`industry averages, or
`tween claim construction and the dam-
`the use of comparables. Allow me to
`ages base is not clear to me. Even a
`provide
`a
`subsection—by-subsection
`concededly limited invention could be
`summary of the bill’s revisions to sec—
`fairly valued by using the full prod-
`tion 284, the basic patent damages stat-
`uct‘s price as the damages base, so long
`ute.
`as the rate applied to that base was ap—
`Subsection (a) of the bill's proposed
`propriately small.
`section 284 copies and recodifies all of
`excessive
`and
`Many
`unjustified
`current section 284,
`including its au-
`awards certainly do use the full value
`thorization of treble damages and its
`of the infringing product as the dam-
`admonition that compensatory dam—
`ages base. Indeed, awards that are de—
`rived from the rule of thumb almost al-
`ages shall “in no event be less than a
`reasonable royalty for the use made of
`ways are based on the entire value of
`the invention.“
`the infringing product, as is the typical
`Subsection (b) codifies current Fed—
`industry averages award. Precluding or
`eral circuit precedent defining a rea-
`sharply limiting the use of net sales
`sonable royalty as the amount that the
`price as a damages base certainly
`infringer and patent owner would have
`would block the path to many of the
`agreed to in a hypothetical negotiation
`bad outcomes that are produced by the
`at
`the time infringement began.
`It
`use of these methodologies.
`tracks the language of the Rite-Hite
`The problem with a rule that bars
`case. 56 F.3d 1538 (Fed. Cir. 1995), and
`the use of net sales price as the dam—
`follow—on decisions. Some supporters of
`ages base when calculating a reason—
`S. 1145 are critical of the hypothetical
`able royalty is that in many industrial
`negotiation construct and believe that
`sectors, net sales price is routinely
`it leads to bad results. Not only is this
`used as the damages base in voluntary
`test established law, however, but it is
`licensing negotiations. It is favored as
`also inherent in the concept of a “rea—
`a damages base because it is an objec-
`sonable royalty." That standard re-
`tive and readily verifiable datum. The
`quires the trier of fact to determine
`parties to a licensing negotiation do
`what would have been—i.e., what the
`not even argue about its use. Instead,
`parties would have agreed to. As long
`they fight over the rate that will be ap-
`as the patent code requires a “reason-
`plied to that base. Even if the net sales
`able royalty,” courts and juries will
`price of the product is very large and
`the economic contribution made by the
`need to engage in a hypothetical in-
`quiry as to how the invention reason—
`patented invention is small, net sales
`ably would have been valued at the
`price can still serve as the denominator
`time of infringement. Indeed, it is not
`of an appropriate royalty if the numer-
`ator is made small.
`apparent by what other means the
`Thus in these industries, the initials,
`factfinder might approach the calcula-
`tion of a reasonable royalty. And in
`NSP, appear frequently and repeatedly
`in licensing contracts. A legal rule that
`any event, the source of occasional bad
`results in damages trials is not
`the
`precluded use of net sales price as the
`mental framework used for approach—
`damages base would effectively prevent
`ing the question of a reasonable roy-
`participants in these industries from
`alty, but rather the particular evidence
`making the same royalty calculations
`and methods used to value some inven-
`in litigation that they would make in
`tions. It would be a noteworthy omis—
`an arm’s length transaction. Such an
`sion to avoid mention of the hypo—
`outcome would be deeply disruptive to
`thetical negotiation concept in a bill
`the valuation of patents in these fields.
`Evidence and techniques whose use is
`that regulates damages analysis to the
`degree that this one does. This sub—
`endorsed by the market via their reg—
`section thus codifies the Federal cir-
`ular use in voluntary negotiations are
`cuit’s
`jurisprudence
`on
`the
`hypo—
`likely to offer the best means of val—
`thetical negotiation.
`uing a patent in litigation. After all,
`Subsection (0) simply makes clear
`what is an object in commerce worth,
`other than what the market is willing
`that, despite subsection (d),
`(e), and
`(f)’s codification and modification of
`to pay? We simply cannot enact a law
`several of the Georgia—Pacific factors,
`that bars patentees from using in liti—
`
`

`

`S9984
`the Georgia—Pacific fac-
`the rest of
`tors—as well as any other appropriate
`factor—may be used as appropriate to
`calculate the amount of a reasonable
`royalty.
`Subsection (d) is probably the most
`important subsection in the bill’s re—
`vised section 284. It bars the use of in-
`dustry averages,
`rule-of—thumb profit
`splits, and other standardized measures
`to value a patent except under par-
`ticular
`circumstances. Standardized
`measures are defined as those methods
`that, like rule of thumb and industry
`averages, do not gauge the particular
`benefits and advantages of the use of a
`patent.
`Instead,
`they are relatively
`crude,
`cookie-cutter measures
`that
`purport
`to value all patents—or at
`least all patents in a class—in the same
`way, without regard to a particular
`patent’s economic value. These back-
`of—the envelope methods are occasion—
`ally used in arm‘s—length, voluntary li—
`censing negotiations,
`as are things
`such as gut instinct and intuition. But
`they are
`rough methods
`that
`can
`produce wildly inaccurate results. Sub—
`section (d) disfavors their use.
`This subsection restricts the use of
`Georgia—Pacific factor 12, which largely
`describes the rule of thumb. Subsection
`(d)‘s general
`rule cites the rule of
`thumb and industry averages as impor-
`tant
`and
`illustrative
`examples
`of
`standardized measures. But it also ex—
`pressly applies to other methods that
`are “not based on the particular bene—
`fits and advantages” of an invention,
`to ensure that variations on these ex-
`amples and other methods that consist
`of the same evil also are brought with-
`in the scope of subsection (d)'s main
`rule.
`An example of a standardized meas-
`ure other than profit splits and indus—
`try averages that is also currently in
`use and that also falls within sub—
`section (d)’s scope is the so—called IBM
`l—percent—up-to—5
`formula. This
`for—
`mula apparently was used by IBM in
`the past to license its own portfolio of
`patents. Under this methodology, each
`patent receives 1 percent of the reve—
`nues on a product until a 5 percent
`ceiling is reached, at which point the
`whole portfolio of patents is made
`available to the licensee.
`I have heard more than one rep-
`resentative of a high—technology com—
`pany describe the use of this formula in
`litigation against his company. Appar—
`ently, there exists a stable of plaintiff—
`side damages expert witnesses who will
`testify that this formula is appropriate
`for and is customarily used to cal—
`culate the value of any patent in the
`computer or information—technologies
`sectors. These experts start at 1 per—
`cent and then adjust
`that number
`based on the other Georgia—Pacific fac—
`tors, supposedly to account for the par-
`ticular aspects of the patent in suit,
`though these adjustments almost
`al—
`ways seem to push the number higher.
`Obviously,
`1 percent of revenues or
`even profits is a grossly inflated value
`for many high—technology patents, It is
`
`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`September 27, 2008
`found the bill ambiguous on this point,
`not uncommon for high—technology
`and in any event the lack of an excep—
`products to be covered by thousands of
`tion would have forced parties to liti-
`different patents, which are of greatly
`gate the question whether an estab-
`differing value. Not every one of those
`lished royalty was,
`in fact, based on
`patents can be worth 1 percent of reve—
`the benefits and advantages of the use
`nues. Some patents inevitably will be
`for features that are trivial, that are
`of the patent. Since established royal—
`ties are widely considered to be the
`irrelevant to consumers, or that could
`gold standard for valuing a patent, we
`be reproduced by unpatented, off—the-
`should avoid making it harder to use
`shelf noninfringing substitutes. One
`this method. It is thus expressly placed
`percent of the sales revenue from, for
`outside the scope of subsection (d)’s re-
`example, a laptop computer is an enor—
`strictions by paragraph (2).
`mous sum of money. Many patents are
`Paragraph (3) of subsection (d) allows
`worth nothing near
`that,
`and any
`industry averages to continue to be
`methodology that starts at that num-
`used to confirm that results produced
`ber is likely to produce a grossly in—
`by
`other,
`independently
`allowable
`flated result in a large number of cases.
`methods fall within a reasonable range.
`It bears also mentioning some of
`The paragraph speaks of “independ-
`those
`common methodologies
`that
`ently" allowable methods in order to
`clearly are not standardized measures.
`make clear that an industry average
`In addition to established royalties,
`cannot be used to confirm an estimate
`which are afforded an express exemp-
`produced solely by reference to a
`tion from this subsection by paragraph
`“comparable” patent. Subsection (e)
`(2),
`there are the methods of calcu-
`requires that comparables only be used
`lating the costs of designing around a
`in conjunction with or to confirm other
`patent. drawing comparisons to the ex—
`methods,
`and thus under
`this bill
`perience of noninfringing alternatives,
`comparables are not a method whose
`or calculating the costs savings pro—
`use is allowed “independently” of other
`duced by use of the invention. All of
`methods.
`these factors gauge the benefits and ad-
`A brief explanation is in order as to
`vantages of the use of the invention
`why this bill regards industry averages
`and therefore are outside the scope of
`as a potentially unreliable metric and
`subsection (d).
`restricts their use. An industry average
`Paragraph (1) of subsection ((1) allows
`often will reflect a broad range of li-
`parties to use a standardized measure,
`censing rates within a technological
`such as a rule—of—thumb profit split, if
`sector. Even a licensed patent whose
`that party can show that the patented
`value is included in the calculation of
`invention is the primary reason why
`such a range may fall at a far end of
`consumers buy the infringing product.
`that
`range, producing highly inac-
`If the patented invention is the pri—
`curate results if that average is used as
`mary reason why people buy the prod-
`a starting point
`for calculating the
`uct, then the patent effectively is the
`value of that patent. Moreover, many
`reason for the commercial success of
`existing patents, though valid and in—
`the product, and its owner is entitled
`fringed by a product, disclose trivial
`to a substantial share of the profits,
`inventions that add little to the value
`minus business risk, marketing, and
`of the product. But the types of patents
`other contributions made by the in—
`that typically are licensed—and that
`fringer.
`therefore would be a source of avail-
`Some have advocated a lower stand-
`able data for calculating an industry
`ard than "primary reason" for allowing
`average—are the ones that are substan—
`use of profit splits and other standard—
`tial and valuable. Trivial patents don't
`ized measures—for example, using a
`"substantial basis” standard. I rejected
`get licensed, and their value does not
`the use of a lower standard because a
`enter
`into industry average calcula—
`tions. Thus particularly in the case of
`profit split should basically award to
`a minor patent that has never been and
`the patent owner all of the profits on
`likely never would be licensed, an in-
`the product minus those attributable
`to business risk. Thus the test for al—
`dustry average would provide an in-
`flated estimate of the patent’s value.
`lowing such profit splits must be one
`This is because the industry average is
`that only one patent will meet per
`not
`the average licensing rate of all
`product, since the bulk of the profits
`patents in a field, but merely the aver—
`can only be awarded once. If the test
`were “substantial basis," for example,
`age of those that have been licensed
`and for which data is publicly avail-
`multiple patents could meet the stand-
`able.
`ard and multiple patent owners could
`Paragraph (4) of subsection (d) cre-
`demand all of the profits minus busi—
`ates a safety valve that allows parties
`ness risk on the product.
`to use standardized measures if no
`Paragraph (2) of subsection ((1) makes
`other method is reasonably available
`established royalties an express excep—
`to calculate a reasonable royalty, and
`tion to the bar on standardized meas—
`the standardized method is otherwise
`ures. In earlier drafts, I did not include
`shown to be appropriate for the patent.
`this exception in the bill because I
`Over the course of drafting this bill, I
`thought it obvious that an established
`have consulted with a number of ex-
`royalty is based on the benefits and ad-
`perts with broad experience in patent
`vantages of the use of the invention
`and is thus outside the scope of the
`damages calculation. Only a few be-
`lieved that they had ever seen a case
`subsection ((1) rule. Some parties who
`where use of a standardized measure
`reviewed those earlier drafts, however,
`
`

`

`S9985
`
`September 27, 2008
`was necessary—that is, where a more
`precise economic analysis was not fea—
`sible. I thus anticipate that this safety
`valve may almost never need to be
`used, but I nevertheless include it in
`the bill, because it is impossible to say
`with certainty that no situation will
`ever arise in the future where parties
`will be unable to calculate a reasonable
`royalty without use of
`the rule of
`thumb or other standardized measures.
`Suffice to say that if one party to a
`suit presents appropriate evidence of a
`patent’s value and that evidence falls
`outside the scope of subsection ((1) or
`within one of
`the other exceptions,
`then that method is "reasonably avail-
`able" and paragraph (4) could not be in—
`voked.
`sub—
`the need for
`A word about
`stantive standards: some critics of S.
`1145 have made the argument
`to me
`that any problems with damages litiga—
`tion can be cured through procedural
`reforms,
`and that changes
`to sub—
`stantive legal standards such as those
`in subsections (d) through (f) are un—
`necessary. These parties
`also have
`made the related, though different ar-
`gument that to the extent that liti—
`gants are using unreliable evidence or
`methodologies, this problem should be
`addressed through cross examination
`and advocacy.
`Though I share these critics’ dis-
`pleasure with S. 1145, I do not think
`that problems such as the overuse of
`rule of thumb and industry averages
`will
`be
`completely solved through
`purely procedural reforms. The most
`likely mechanism for excluding these
`methodologies would be rule 702. But
`the use of some of these methods for
`valuing patents is endorsed by multiple
`experts. These methods, while ulti—
`mately unsound,
`represent a signifi—
`cant minority view that is backed by
`some published commentary,
`albeit
`sometimes only commentary in jour—
`nals that are exclusively written by,
`subscribed to, and read by plaintiff—side
`damages expert witnesses. In such cir—
`cumstances, it is no sure thing that a
`party will be able to exclude under
`Daubert
`the testimony of an expert
`employing these methodologies. These
`metrics
`are
`sufficiently entrenched
`that the only way to ensure that the
`courts will disallow them when their
`use is not appropriate is for Congress
`to tell the courts to disallow them.
`As to the second point, it is true that
`it is the lawyer’s duty to identify the
`flaws in the other side‘s arguments and
`to debunk unsound theories. But the
`reality is that because of the limited
`expertise and experience of many ju—
`rors and the limited time allowed to
`argue a case at trial, often the trier of
`fact will not divine the truth of the
`matter. And some unsound damages
`methodologies are particularly likely
`to be appealing to those untutored in
`the field. An industry average analysis,
`for example, employs the one statis-
`tical concept that is understood by vir—
`tually everyone, and this method’s use
`may amount to no more than a simple
`
`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`too broad. Parties might define “indus—
`try” so expansively that every patent
`in the universe would fall into one of
`only two or three “industries."
`Paragraph (2) of subsection (e) sets
`out guideposts for determining whether
`a patent is economically comparable to
`another patent. It suggests requiring a
`showing that the supposed comparable
`is of similar significance to the li-
`censed product as the patent in suit is
`to the infringing product, and that the
`licensed and infringing products have a
`similar profit margin. Obviously, a pat—
`ent that makes only a trivial contribu-
`tion to a product cannot accurately be
`valued by reference to a comparable
`that makes a critical and valuable con-
`tribution to its licensed product, or
`vice versa. And similarity in the profit—
`ability of the licensed and infringing
`products will also generally be impor—
`tant to establishing the economic com—
`parability of two patents. As an eco—
`nomic reality, when the profits on a
`product are high,
`the manufacturer
`will be more generous with the royal-
`ties that he pays for the patented in-
`ventions that are used by the product.
`This economic reality is undergirded
`by the fact that it will typically be the
`patented inventions used by a product
`that make that product unique in the
`marketplace and allow it to earn high—
`er profits. Even if two patents are the
`principal patent on products in the
`same field, if one patent’s product has
`a 2—percent profit margin and the oth—
`er's has a 20-percent profit margin.
`that first patent evidently is doing less
`to distinguish that product in its mar-
`ket and to generate consumer
`de—
`mand—and thus has a lower economic
`value.
`com—
`of
`analysis
`thorough
`A
`parability, of course, likely will depend
`in a given case on many factors beyond
`those listed here. Subparagraphs (A)
`and (B) are simply guideposts that de—
`scribe two factors that are likely to be
`relevant
`to comparability. The bill
`only provides that these two factors
`may be considered. It does not preclude
`consideration of other factors, nor does
`it require that
`these two factors be
`considered in every case. A party as-
`serting the propriety of a comparable
`may be able to show that one or even
`both of these factors are not appro—
`priate to establishing economic com-
`parability in a given case.
`Subsection (f) bars parties from argu—
`ing that damages should be based on
`the wealth or profitability of the de-
`fendant as of the time of trial. Some
`lawyers have been known, after mak—
`ing their case for an inflated royalty
`calculation,
`to emphasize how insig—
`nificant even that inflated request is in
`light of the total revenues of the de—
`fendant infringer. Such arguments do
`not assist the jury in gauging a reason-
`able royalty. Rather, they serve to re—
`duce the jury’s sense of responsibility
`to limit a reasonable royalty to the ac-
`tual value of the use made of the inven—
`tion. This subsection does not bar all
`
`back-of—the—envelope calculation that
`requires only one expert
`to give you
`the industry average licensing rate and
`another to calculate the gross revenues
`on the product. When a complex eco—
`nomic analysis that
`focuses on non—
`infringing alternatives to the patented
`invention or
`the costs of a design—
`around is forced to compete for the
`jury’s favor with a simple average—rate—
`times—sales calculation, many jurors
`may find the simpler and readily un—
`derstandable method more intuitively
`appealing, even if it is less accurate.
`And of course, when two different and
`even slightly complex damages calcula—
`tions are presented to a jury, there al—
`ways exists a risk that the jury will re—
`solve the dispute by splitting the dif—
`ference between the two methods. In a
`high—value case where the patent owner
`uses an unsound method that produces
`a wildly inflated number, the risk that
`the jury will pick the wrong method or
`even split the difference may easily be
`unacceptable from a business perspec—
`tive.
`In the end, it is the premise of the
`rules of evidence that some types of
`evidence are so unsound, so prejudicial,
`or so likely to produce an unjust result
`that we do not require the other side‘s
`lawyer to debunk this evidence, but
`rather we require the judge to bar it
`from the courtroom altogether. If we
`find that particular methodologies rou—
`tinely produce inaccurate and unjust
`results,
`it
`is appropriate that we
`amend the law to directly restrict the
`use of those methodologies.
`Subsection (6) restricts and regulates
`the use of licenses paid for supposedly
`comparable patents as a means of cal-
`culating the value of the patent in suit.
`The use of comparables is authorized
`by Georgia-Pacific factor two and can
`generate probative evidence of a pat—
`ent’s value. Nevertheless, such use is
`regulated and restricted by this sub—
`section. Comparables are a valuation
`method that is often abused, both to
`overvalue and to undervalue patents.
`When an infringer is sued for infringing
`an important patent, he often will cite
`as evidence of a reasonable royalty the
`license paid for a patent that is in the
`same field but that is much less valu—
`able than the patent in suit. Similarly,
`a plaintiff patent owner asserting a
`trivial patent may cite
`as
`“com—
`parable” other patents in the same
`field that are much more valuable than
`the plaintiff‘s patent. The fact that an—
`other patent is licensed in the same in—
`dustry should not alone be enough to
`allow its use as a comparable in litiga—
`tion.
`Comparability is a subjective test.
`By definition, every patent is unique
`and no two patents are truly com—
`parable. Subsection (e)
`thus requires
`that comparables be used only in con-
`junction with or to confirm the results
`of other evidence, and that they only
`be drawn from the same or an analo—
`gous technological
`field.
`I chose the
`latter term rather than “same indus—
`try” because the term “industry” is
`
`

`

`CONGRESSIONAL RECORD — SENATE
`S9986
`September 27, 2008
`that exist only in litigation expert wit-
`condi—
`the financial
`consideration of
`ness‘
`testimony and are never em-
`tion of the infringer. It may be appro—
`ployed in actual licensing negotiations.
`priate to consider
`the infringer’s fi—
`Use of this reliability indicator should
`nances at the time of infringement es-
`inject more honesty into the hypo-
`pecially if there is some evidence that
`such information is considered when li—
`thetical negotiation. It should force
`parties to use methodologies that actu-
`censing patents in the relevant indus—
`ally would have been used had the in-
`try. But in no case should a court allow
`such information to be presented when
`fringer and claimant negotiated a li—
`cense, rather than metrics that are
`the evident purpose of doing is to tell
`only ever employed in an expert’s
`the jury that the defendant has deep
`imaginary parallel universe.
`pockets and will not be burdened by an
`inflated award.
`The second new reliability indicator,
`whether the expert has accounted for
`Subsection (g) gives either party a
`readily available alternative theories,
`presumptive right to demand that va-
`should exclude the expert who ignores
`lidity and infringement be decided be—
`precise and objective metrics of value
`fore the jury hears arguments about
`damages. Currently,
`some plaintiffs
`in favor of subjective and manipulable
`methodologies
`that
`allow him to
`will
`force a premature debate over
`produce the result
`that happens to
`damages in order to color the jury's
`most favor his client. If there is clear
`view of validity and infringement. For
`evidence, for example, of the market
`example,
`in some cases, the same de—
`fense witness who testifies as to valid-
`price of a noninfringing alternative to
`ity and infringement will also know
`the infringing product, of the costs of
`facts relevant
`to the patent‘s value.
`noninfringing substitutes for
`the in—
`vention or the costs of a design—around,
`This may allow the plaintiff’s lawyer
`or of the cost savings produced by use
`to question that witness about dam—
`of
`the invention, an expert witness
`ages, forcing the defendant to begin ar—
`should not be allowed to ignore that
`guing about the amount of his liability
`evidence. He must consider that evi—
`before the jury has even heard all the
`dence or at least provide a persuasive
`arguments as to whether the patent is
`account as to why it should not be con-
`valid and infringed. A defendant who is
`sidered. One common sign of a bad or
`already arguing about what a patent is
`worth will tend to look as if he has al—
`biased expert witness is his disregard of
`ready conceded that he owes
`some—
`readily available alternative theories
`or techniques. Paragraph (6) will help
`thing, and that the dispute is simply
`over the amount.
`to ensure that Federal courts exercise
`This tension also exists even when all
`their gatekeeper role and bar such wit—
`validity and infringement arguments
`nesses from misleading the jury.
`Finally, subsection (c) of proposed
`are presented before damages are ar—
`section 299A requires district courts
`gued. Current law routinely allows the
`defendant to be forced to argue in the
`and circuit courts to explain their
`alternative to be made to argue in one
`Daubert determinations, which should
`breath that he is not liable and in the
`facilitate appeal of those decisions.
`Section 5 of the bill authorizes the
`next that if he is liable, then this is the
`creation of post grant
`review pro-
`amount for which he is liable. A pre—
`ceedings for challenging the validity of
`sumptive right to have one issue re-
`solved before the other is addressed
`patents. It allows both first— and sec—
`ond-window review of a patent, with
`would cure this tension. This
`sub—
`procedural restrictions that will limit
`section allows only sequencing of the
`the time and expense of
`these pro-
`trial, not full bifurcation. It does not
`ceedings and protect patent owners.
`require the use of a second jury, and al-
`The bill uses a procedural model that is
`lows all pretrial activity,
`including
`favored by PTO and is calculated to
`that related to damages,
`to be com-
`allow quick resolution of petitions. Im-
`pleted before the validity and infringe—
`portantly. the bill also imposes proce—
`ment case is presented and decided.
`dural limits on when a second-window
`The jury would decide validity and in-
`proceeding may be sought after civil
`fringement and then proceed imme-
`litigation has
`commenced.
`and re-
`diately to hear the damages case,
`if
`still needed.
`stricts duplicative or second and suc-
`Subsection (h) requires an expert to
`cessive proceedings, preventing infring—
`ers from using post grant review as a
`provide to the opposing party his writ—
`litigation or delaying tactic.
`ten testimony and the data and other
`information on which his conclusions
`Section 5(a) of the bill repeals the
`and methods are based, and to also pro—
`procedures for inter partes reexam ef—
`fective 1 year after the date of enact—
`vide the written testimony to the
`ment of the bill, while allowing re—
`court. This
`subsection supplements
`quests for reexam that are filed before
`current
`law, codifying and enforcing
`that effective date to continue to be
`the better interpretation of what
`is
`considered by the office. Director—initi—
`currently required by the rules of pro-
`ated reexam is also repealed, out of
`cedure. It is necessary because those
`current rules are sometimes not fully
`concern that
`in the future political
`pressure may be brought
`to bear on
`enforced, and experts sometimes are al-
`PTO to attack patents that are a nui—
`lowed to testify,
`for example, as to
`sance to politically important busi—
`what is customary in an industry with—
`nesses.
`out providing the facts and figures or
`The bill’s proposed section 321 au—
`evidence of actual events that are the
`thorizes two types of post grant review
`basis for the expert’s view that some-
`
`thing is customary. Rule 702 exists to
`ensure that expert witnesses are not
`simply allowed to argue from author—
`ity. It allows opposing counsel to chal—
`lenge the expert’s methods as unsound,
`but that right becomes illusory if the
`expert
`is allowed to testify without
`ever disclosing an objective foundation
`for his conclusions. Requiring the ex-
`pert’s written testimony to also be pro-
`vided to the judge should allow the
`ju

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket