throbber
Tom Ewing & Robin Feldman: The Giants Among Us
`
`Law Review
`
`Stanford
`
`The Giants Among Us
`
`TOM EWING & ROBIN FELDMAN*
`
`CITE AS: 2012 STAN. TECH. L. REV. 1
`
`http://stlr.stanford.edu/pdf/feldman—giants-among—us.pdf
`
`“ © Thomas Ewing, JD, MS, MA, Licentiate in Industrial Management & Economics (expected 2012); Robin Feldman,
`Professor of Law 8: Director of LAB Project, UC Hastings Law. \Ve are grateful to Ben DePoorter, Josh Horowitz, Jonathan
`Masur, Darien Shanske, Steve Tadelis, Ove Granstrand, and Marcus Finléif Holgersson. We would also like to thanszmes Nolan,
`Patricia Dyck, Chris Johnson, Sandy Liu, Jason Ross, \Villiams Casey, Leanne Yu, and Elaine Zhong for their excellent research
`assistance.
`
`IVM v. Xilinx
`
`Exhibit — XLNX-2002
`
`Trial Number: lPR2012-00018
`
`XLNX—ZOOZ — Page 1
`
`

`

`Tom Ewing & Robin Feldman: The Giants Among Us
`
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`
`INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................................................................ 1
`
`I. FACTS .............................................................................................................................................................. 2
`A. Intellectual Ventures...................................................................................................................................... 3
`B. Patents and Applications Held by Intellectual Ventures ................................................................................. 5
`C. Origins of the Portfolio ................................................................................................................................... 7
`C. Funding Sources............................................................................................................................................. 9
`D. Return on Investment..................................................................................................................................... 9
`E. Collecting Revenue: Privateering & Other Exploits ..................................................................................... 12
`F. Other Mass Aggregators & Interconnections................................................................................................. 15
`
`
`II. POTENTIAL POSITIVE EFFECTS..................................................................................................... 18
`A. The Forgotten Inventor ................................................................................................................................ 18
`B. The Middleman............................................................................................................................................ 20
`C. The Litigation Defense Fund ....................................................................................................................... 21
`
`
`III. POTENTIAL HARMS............................................................................................................................. 23
`A. A Tax on Production.................................................................................................................................. 25
`B. Opportunities for Anticompetitive Conduct ................................................................................................... 26
`C. Raising Rivals’ Costs................................................................................................................................... 26
`D. Other Troubling Market Behavior............................................................................................................... 28
`E. Odd Characteristics of the Inputs Supplying the Market............................................................................... 29
`F. Odd Characteristics of the Aggregator Business............................................................................................. 30
`G. Economic Stability....................................................................................................................................... 31
`H. “To Serve Man” ......................................................................................................................................... 32
`I. Ancillary Implications ................................................................................................................................... 33
`
`
`IV. A FEW OBSERVATIONS...................................................................................................................... 35
`A. Regulatory Oversight.................................................................................................................................... 35
`B. Let the Sun Shine In.................................................................................................................................... 37
`C. Removing the Teeth of the Tiger.................................................................................................................... 41
`
`
`CONCLUSION ................................................................................................................................................ 41
`
`APPENDIX A .................................................................................................................................................. 43
`
`APPENDIX B................................................................................................................................................... 44
`
`APPENDIX C................................................................................................................................................... 47
`
`XLNX-2002 - Page 2
`
`

`

`¶1
`
`¶2
`
`¶3
`
`¶4
`
`¶5
`
`Robin Feldman & Tom Ewing: The Giants Among Us
`
`1
`
`
`
`
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`
`
`The patent world is quietly undergoing a change of seismic proportions. In a few short years, a
`handful of entities have amassed vast treasuries of patents on an unprecedented scale. To give some
`sense of the magnitude of this change, our research shows that in a little more than five years, the
`most massive of these has accumulated 30,000-60,000 patents worldwide, which would make it the
`5th largest patent portfolio of any domestic US company and the 15th largest of any company in the
`world.
`Although size is important in understanding the nature of the shift, size alone is not the issue. It
`is also the method of organization and the types of activities that are causing a paradigm shift in the
`world of patents and innovation.
`These entities, which we call mass aggregators, do not engage in the manufacturing of products
`nor do they conduct much research. Rather, they pursue other goals of interest to their founders and
`investors. Non-practicing entities have been around the patent world for some time, and in the past,
`they have fallen into two broad categories.1 The first category includes universities and research
`laboratories, which tend to have scholars engaged in basic research and license out inventions rather
`than manufacturing products on their own. The second category includes individuals or small groups
`who purchase patents to assert them against existing, successful products. Those in the second
`category have been described colloquially as “trolls,” which appears to be a reference to the
`children’s tale of the three billy goats who must pay a toll to the troll waiting under the bridge if they
`wish to pass. Troll activity is generally reviled by operating companies as falling somewhere between
`extortion and a drag on innovation.2 In particular, many believe that patent trolls often extract a
`disproportionate return, far beyond the value that their patented invention adds to the commercial
`product, if it adds at all.3
`The new mass aggregator, however, is an entirely different beast. To begin with, funding sources
`for mass aggregators include some very successful and respectable organizations, including
`manufacturing companies such as Apple, eBay, Google, Intel, Microsoft, Nokia, and Sony, as well as
`academic institutions such as the University of Pennsylvania and Notre Dame, and other entities
`such as the World Bank and the William and Flora Hewlett Foundation. Nations such as China,
`France, South Korea, and Taiwan even have their own mass aggregators to varying degrees.
`Moreover, the acquisition appetites and patent supply sources are quite interesting. Mass
`aggregators may have portfolios that range across vastly different areas of innovation from
`computers to telecommunications to biomedicine to nanotechnology.4 In some of the acquisition
`
`
`1 Sannu K. Shrestha, Trolls or Market Makers? An Empirical Analysis of Nonpracticing Entities, 110 COLUM. L. REV. 114, 115
`(“NPEs are firms that rarely or never practice their patents, instead focusing on earning licensing fees.”); U.S. FED. TRADE
`COMM’N, THE EVOLVING IP MARKETPLACE: ALIGNING PATENT NOTICE AND REMEDIES WITH COMPETITION, 2011 WL
`838912 at 60 (2011), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2011/03/110307patentreport.pdf (“NPE also commonly refers to firms
`that obtain nearly all of their patents through acquisition or purchase in order to assert them against manufacturers.”); see also
`Colleen V. Chien, Of Trolls, Davids, Goliaths, and Kings: Narratives and Evidence in the Litigation of High-Tech Patents, 87 N.C. L. REV.
`1571, 1572 (2009).
`2 Chien, supra note 1 at 1577-78 (“The term NPE generally refers to a patentee that does not make products or ‘practice’ its
`inventions.”); Jeremiah S. Helm, Comment, Why Pharmaceutical Firms Support Patent Trolls: The Disparate Impact of eBay v.
`Mercexchange on Innovation, 13 MICH. TELECOMM. & TECH. L. REV. 331, 333 (2006) (distinguishing between universities and
`patent trolls); Mark A. Lemley, Are Universities Patent Trolls?, 18 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 611, 629-30 (2008)
`(distinguishing between universities as non-practicing entities and trolls); Gerard N. Magliocca, Blackberries and Barnyards: Patent
`Trolls and the Perils of Innovation, 82 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 1809, 1810 (2007) (“‘[P]atent troll’ . . . is a derogatory term for firms that
`use their patents to extract settlements rather than license or manufacture technology.”); see also Jay P. Kesan, Transferring Innovation,
`77 FORDHAM L. REV. 2169, 2193 (2009) (cautioning universities against appearing troll-like because patent trolls are perceived
`unsympathetically).
`3 See Lemley, supra note 2, at 613-14; Magliocca, supra note 2 at 1810 (“Critics claim that these firms are little more than
`blackmailers who put a crippling tax on productive enterprises.”).
`4 Pharmaceuticals seems to be the one technical area generally excluded from mass aggregation, perhaps because the
`pharmaceutical innovation system has evolved to include lesser degrees of technical sharing.
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2011 Stanford Technology Law Review. All Rights Reserved.
`
`XLNX-2002 - Page 3
`
`

`

`¶6
`
`¶7
`
`¶8
`
`¶9
`
`¶10
`
`¶11
`
`Robin Feldman & Tom Ewing: The Giants Among Us
`
`2
`
`activity, mass aggregators purchase large chunks, and even the majority, of an operating company’s
`patents and patent applications. They typically pay cash up front, as well as a share of any future
`profits generated from asserting the patents against anyone other than the selling manufacturer. Mass
`aggregators have engaged in other unusual acquisition approaches as well, including purportedly
`purchasing the rights to all future inventions by researchers at universities in developing countries.
`Other acquisition approaches purportedly include targeted purchases of patents that are of particular
`interest to the mass aggregators’ investors.
`The types of returns promised to investors and the types of benefits offered to participants are
`also quite different from garden-variety non-practicing entities, as are some of the tactics used in
`organizing the entities and in asserting the patents. Finally, the scale itself is simply mind-boggling.
`Mass aggregators operate on a scale and at a level of sophistication and complexity that would have
`been unimaginable a decade ago. They have taken the prototype strategies pioneered by a prior
`generation of non-practicing entities and changed them into some of the cleverest strategies yet seen
`in the intellectual property rights field.
`The goal of this article is to shed some light on mass aggregators. We hope to provide some
`understanding of the nature of the change, to analyze its economics and implications, and to offer
`some normative considerations. In the descriptive section, we focus on the oldest and largest of the
`mass aggregators, Intellectual Ventures, which has gone to great lengths to maintain secrecy.
`Working from public sources and investing thousands of hours of research, we offer a detailed
`picture of the entity, tracing through approximately 1300 shell companies and thousands of patents.
`The section also describes in brief form several other mass aggregators, including ones that are public
`companies.
`In the analytic section, we examine the potential implications of mass aggregators for the patent
`system specifically, for innovation in general, and for the economy as a whole. We look at the
`potential positive effects that mass aggregators might bring, including facilitating appropriate rewards
`for forgotten inventors, creating a market to connect innovators with those who can manufacture
`their inventions, and, most important, operating as a form of insurance—something akin to an Anti-
`Troll defense fund.
`On the other side, we look at the potential economic dangers of mass aggregators and the
`market for patent monetization they create. Given the imperfections of the patent system and the
`odd characteristics of the product created by the market for patent monetization, mass aggregators
`may serve as a tax on current production that reduces future innovation. Characteristics of the
`market may also provide opportunities for anticompetitive behavior.
`Finally, we offer a few preliminary, normative observations on whether and to what extent the
`sovereign, in the form of various governmental bodies, should become involved in these market-level
`changes. The section also considers broadly the types of changes that would have to occur for such
`participation to take place in a meaningful and minimally disruptive fashion.
`
`I. FACTS
`
`Over the last five years, information about mass aggregators has slowly filtered out into the
`patent community. Initial information was fueled largely by speculation as well as quiet, oblique
`comments from those bound by confidentiality agreements or concerned about incurring the wrath
`of the aggregators. As a reporter researching one of the mass aggregators noted as recently as July
`2011,
`[W]e called people who had licensing arrangements with [Intellectual Ventures], we called
`people who were defendants in lawsuits involving [Intellectual Ventures] patents, we called
`every single company being sued by Oasis Research. No one would talk to us.5
`
`
`5 Alex Blumberg & Laura Sydell, This American Life: When Patents Attack (National Public Radio broadcast, July 22, 2011)
`(transcript available at http://www.npr.org/blogs/money/2011/07/25/138576167/when-patents-attack)
`(noting
`that
`the
`
`
`Copyright © 2011 Stanford Technology Law Review. All Rights Reserved.
`
`XLNX-2002 - Page 4
`
`

`

`¶12
`
`¶13
`
`¶14
`
`¶15
`
`¶16
`
`¶17
`
`¶18
`
`Robin Feldman & Tom Ewing: The Giants Among Us
`
`3
`
`We encountered similar reticence when we first began trying to understand the structure and
`activities of aggregators. “You can’t find out anything about them; don’t even try,” is a chant that has
`been whispered in intellectual property circles for a number of years. It motivated us to take a hard
`look, and the information eventually unraveled like the yarn from an old sweater.
`A literature search on Intellectual Ventures reveals many opinions about the company but few
`independent facts. We have aimed to fill that void by tracing the intellectual property assets that the
`company appears to own, identifying the sources of those assets, and describing the company’s
`activities. The data we provide here is the result of four years of painstaking research, piecing
`together bits of information available from public sources.
`
`A. Intellectual Ventures
`
`Much about Intellectual Ventures is shrouded in secrecy. Intellectual Ventures has acknowledged
`that it intentionally withholds the true scope and nature of its IP portfolio.6 Its licensing transactions
`and interactions are protected by strict nondisclosure agreements, and the structure of its business
`activities makes it difficult to get a handle on the full extent of its activities. For example, our
`research has identified more than a thousand shell companies that Intellectual Ventures has used to
`conduct its intellectual property acquisitions, and it has taken considerable effort to identify these.
`The range and scope of its activities are so vast that it is difficult to conceptualize the reach of
`Intellectual Ventures.
`Intellectual Ventures was founded in 2000 by Nathan Myhrvold and Edward Jung, both of
`whom formerly served in high-level positions at Microsoft.7 Peter Detkin also played a key
`management role in developing Intellectual Ventures.8 In one of patent law’s great ironies, Detkin
`coined the derogatory term “patent troll” during his tenure as the chief intellectual property officer at
`Intel.9
`Although operations began in 2000, Intellectual Ventures does not appear to have begun its
`massive patent acquisitions in earnest until somewhere around 2004 or 2005, when the annual
`number of acquisitions transaction we could identify rose from a handful to several hundred.
`According to Intellectual Ventures, invention per se is its product, and both Myhrvold and Detkin
`have referred to the company’s business model as “Invention Capitalism.” They define Invention
`Capitalism as applying concepts from venture capital and private equity to develop and commercially
`exploit new inventions.10
`Although Intellectual Ventures is designed to make money from trading in patent rights, the
`founders describe their activities as ones that will incentivize research and development in all
`technical subjects. Myhrvold, for example, has been quoted as saying the following:
`Most of people think of research as a charity, a philanthropic thing. They don’t view it as a
`for-profit venture. So our goal is to make research something you can invest in. I think it’s
`
`reluctance was fueled in part by fear and in part by Intellectual Ventures’ nondisclosure agreement, rumored to be the strictest in
`Silicon Valley).
`6 See Victoria Slind-Flor, The Goodfellas: Detkin and Myhrvold on Patents, Trolls & Intellectual Ventures, 19 INTELL. ASSET MGMT.
`28, 34 (noting that Intellectual Ventures will not reveal how many patents it has or the entities to which it has licensed technology,
`and quoting Myhrvold’s response that “We’re a private company. We don’t disclose our investment plans any more than Warren
`Buffet does.”); see also Steve Lohr, Turning Patents into ‘Invention Capital’, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 18, 2010, at B1 (paraphrasing Myhrvold as
`saying that Intellectual Venture’s “penchant for secrecy” is a legacy from its startup days when it “did not want to tip its hand”).
`7 Intellectual Ventures LLC was formed on September 21, 1999. Corporations Division – Registration Data Search, WASH.
`SEC. OF STATE, http://www.sos.wa.gov/corps/search_detail.aspx?ubi=601981783 (last visited Nov. 15, 2011). Nathan Myhrvold
`formerly served as Microsoft’s chief technology officer, and Jung served as Microsoft’s chief architect. Our Team, INTELLECTUAL
`VENTURES, http://intellectualventures.com/WhoWeAre/OurTeam.aspx (last visited Nov. 15, 2011).
`8 Detkin joined Intellectual Ventures in 2002. Peter N. Detkin, Leveling the Patent Playing Field, 6 J. MARSHALL REV. INTELL.
`PROP. L. 636 n.* (2007), available at http://www.jmripl.com/Publications/Vol6/Issue4/Detkin.pdf.
`9 Id. at 636 (stating that he coined the term); Brenda Sandburg, You May Not Have a Choice. Trolling for Dollars, THE RECORDER
`(July 30, 2001), http://www.phonetel.com/pdfs/LWTrolls.pdf (using the term and attributing it to Detkin).
`10 See Detkin, supra note 8, at 636 n.*; Lohr, supra note 6 (citing Nathan Myhrvold); Nathan Myhrvold, The Big Idea: Funding
`Eureka, HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW, Mar. 2010, at 40, available at http://hbr.org/2010/03/the-big-idea-funding-eureka/ar/1.
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2011 Stanford Technology Law Review. All Rights Reserved.
`
`XLNX-2002 - Page 5
`
`

`

`¶19
`
`¶20
`
`¶21
`
`¶22
`
`¶23
`
`Robin Feldman & Tom Ewing: The Giants Among Us
`
`4
`
`a valuable investment if you know what you’re doing. So we think that if we supply capital
`and expertise in the right way then we can make a hell of an investment and if we are
`successful at doing it, the net research budget will go up.11
`The scope of Intellectual Ventures’ activities is so vast that it is difficult to contemplate the reach
`of the company. It has invested in innovations and technologies across a broad spectrum of
`industries—everything from computer hardware to biomedicine to consumer electronics to
`nanotechnology. In more than 1,000 transactions, by our count, the company has acquired
`inventions and related intellectual property from individual inventors, corporations of all sizes,
`governments, research laboratories, and universities.
`Getting a handle on the scope and activities of an entity as secretive as Intellectual Ventures is
`not easy.12 We have tried to create a picture of the company by piecing together information from
`publicly available sources. These sources include the patent assignment records of the United States
`Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO); the USPTO’s PAIR database,13 which includes the file
`histories of patents; the USPTO’s patent and application database; government records for key
`states, including Delaware, Nevada, Washington, and California; Internal Revenue Service filings for
`non-profit entities; Securities and Exchange Commission data from 10Q and 10K filings by
`corporations; the Federal Register; filings made in dozens of litigations; and press releases and other
`publications from various entities.
`The structure of the Intellectual Ventures network of operations makes it tremendously difficult
`to detect and trace the company’s activities. For example, Intellectual Ventures has acknowledged
`that it uses shell companies for purchasing and holding patents, although it has not publicly identified
`the number of shells or their names.14 In 2006, one magazine identified 50 shell companies that it
`believed were being operated by Intellectual Ventures. Our research has pieced together 1276 shell
`companies associated with Intellectual Ventures. We do not believe that we have identified all of the
`Intellectual Ventures shell companies, but these 1276 companies alone hold roughly 8000 US patents
`and 3000 pending US patent applications as of May 2011.15
`Even with some knowledge of the shell companies, tracking the Intellectual Ventures portfolio is
`complicated by the fact that Intellectual Ventures has at times neglected to record its ownership for
`long periods of time. In some cases, for example, we found parties indicating that they had sold or
`licensed patents to Intellectual Ventures—even to the point of identifying the intellectual property
`with great particularity—but we could not locate a corresponding assignment in the USPTO
`database.16
`Although Intellectual Ventures has never divulged the precise nature and extent of its portfolio,
`the company has reported that it holds some 35,000 “invention assets.”17 The company does not
`define the term, but we assume that this phrase refers not only to patents but also to patent
`applications, non-filed invention disclosures,18 design patents, trademarks, and any trade secrets
`
`11 Nathan Myhrvold, Speech at the Churchill Club in Palo Alto, CA (Feb. 27, 2007).
`12 Credit for this exhaustive research goes to co-author Tom Ewing.
`13 PAIR stands for Patent Application Information Retrieval.
`14 See Slind-Flor, supra note 6, at 32 (quoting Peter Detkin as acknowledging that Intellectual Ventures uses shells for
`acquisitions and noting that many companies do this to keep potential liabilities of the acquired company from affecting the whole
`organization).
`15 At least 175 of the patents acquired by Intellectual Ventures have reached the end of their terms and expired. Likewise,
`many more of their patents will expire in just a few years. We have not checked patent maintenance fee payment information to
`determine if any of the other patents have expired due to failure to pay maintenance fees. In any event, the “active” US portfolio is
`likely a bit smaller than suggested by the numbers above.
`16 In one case, Intellectual Ventures opted not to record a change of ownership for 2506 days following execution. An
`assignment for US Publication No. 20090254972 was executed on Aug. 9, 2002, but not recorded until June 19, 2009. See , USPTO
`ASSIGNMENTS ON THE WEB, http://assignments.uspto.gov/assignments/?db=pat (search “Publication Number” for
`“20090254972”).
`17 Press Release, Intellectual Ventures, BlueCat Networks Signs Patent Agreement With Intellectual Ventures (June 28, 2011),
`available at http://intellectualventures.com/newsroom/pressreleases/11-06-
`28/BlueCat_Networks_Signs_Patent_Agreement_With_Intellectual_Ventures.aspx.
`18 The company has claimed to have some 3000 unfiled invention disclosures. See Tom Ewing, Inside the World of Public
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2011 Stanford Technology Law Review. All Rights Reserved.
`
`XLNX-2002 - Page 6
`
`

`

`¶24
`
`¶25
`
`¶26
`
`¶27
`
`Robin Feldman & Tom Ewing: The Giants Among Us
`
`5
`
`owned or licensed by the company. Further confusing the issue is whether the company counts as
`“invention assets” patents or only patent families. The company also is not clear about where these
`assets exist, but we assume that this number represents the company’s worldwide portfolio. If the
`35,000 number were to represent the company’s United States portfolio alone, Intellectual Ventures
`would hold a portfolio larger than IBM’s United States portfolio, which is generally acknowledged as
`the largest domestic portfolio.
`To give a fuller picture of precisely what Intellectual Ventures owns, we assembled as much
`information as possible from public sources on the company’s holdings that are actually patents. To
`summarize the information below, we estimate that Intellectual Ventures has a worldwide portfolio
`of 30,000-60,000 patents and applications as of May 2011. This would mean that in just a few short
`years, Intellectual Ventures has acquired at least the 5th largest patent portfolio among US companies
`and approximately the 15th largest patent portfolio worldwide.19
`
`B. Patents and Applications Held by Intellectual Ventures
`
`With a great deal of digging, we were able to locate 1276 shell companies and related entities that
`appear to be associated with Intellectual Ventures.20 These companies hold approximately 8000 US
`patents and 3000 pending US patent applications. We do not believe that we have found all of the
`shell companies.21 Nevertheless, we believe we can calculate a reasonable approximation of
`Intellectual Ventures’ patent holdings. The overall size of Intellectual Venture’s portfolio can be
`estimated in several ways based on the information that we have obtained. The estimate below comes
`from what we have learned about these 1276 shell companies.22
`We begin by using information about Intellectual Venture’s shell companies. First, we have
`identified some 50 shells that appear to serve a management function, one shell that serves a
`trademark function, a dozen or so that serve investment functions. Of the remaining 1200
`companies, 954 companies have patents recorded against their names, and some 242 shells do not
`have patents recorded against their names, although some of them clearly hold licensed-in patent
`rights.
`We have noticed that Intellectual Ventures has a pattern of establishing a shell to receive assets
`well before the transaction related to those assets has been completed. Thus, we suspect that at least
`some of the 242 companies without patents recorded against their names are awaiting allocation of
`assets from a patent-related transaction. We suspect that others have already experienced a patent-
`related transaction, but that the transaction has yet to surface in the public record. For example, if
`Intellectual Ventures receives an exclusive license to a patent, the effect would be similar to owning
`the patent outright, but the parties would not necessarily record a change of patent ownership with
`
`
`Auctions, 42 INTELL. ASSET MGMT. 67 (2010).
`19 Patent holdings are difficult to compare and rank because, among other things, to be completely accurate, one must
`account for patents expired on the basis of age and/or failure to pay annuity/maintenance fees.
`20 The shell companies that we know about seem to serve the following functions: 1201 patent holding shells, 1 trademark
`holding shell, 51 asset management shells, and 24 executive and investment shells. See Appendix C for a further discussion of
`research methodology.
`21 As noted elsewhere, we have found approximately 100 other companies registered in Delaware that appear to be shell
`companies but do not presently hold patents. We will continue to monitor these companies.
`22 The size of Intellectual Ventures’ portfolio can also be estimated based upon how much the company has spent acquiring
`this portfolio and how much they have spent per patent. As an arbitrage buyer, one could assume that Intellectual Ventures spends
`roughly the same amount per patent in all of its purchases. Myhrvold reported that Intellectual Ventures had spent $1.163 billion
`acquiring patents by May, 2009. Nigel Page, IV Shifts Gear, 36 INTELL. ASSET MAG. 9, 10 (2009). In a study of Ocean Tomo patent
`auctions, we concluded that Intellectual Ventures had spent a little more than $61 million acquiring 410 US patents and their
`foreign counterparts at an average cost of $148,966 per US patent obtained. Tom Ewing, Publicly Auctioned Patent Buyers, 34
`AVANCEPT (2010). Some published reports have said that Intellectual Ventures pays only $40,000 per patent. Page, supra at 13.
`Application of this information combined with additional information about the growth of Intellectual Ventures’ portfolio since
`May, 2009 leads to an estimated US portfolio of 10,149 US patents and 27,649 foreign patents by May, 2011 along with several
`thousand pending applications worldwide. This second estimate fits well with the estimate based upon analysis of patent-holding
`shell companies.
`
`
`
`Copyright © 2011 Stanford Technology Law Review. All Rights Reserved.
`
`XLNX-2002 - Page 7
`
`

`

`¶28
`
`¶29
`
`¶30
`
`¶31
`
`¶32
`
`¶33
`
`Robin Feldman & Tom Ewing: The Giants Among Us
`
`6
`
`the USPTO, especially if the recipient of the exclusive license believed it highly unlikely that the
`registered patent owner would resell the patent to someone else.
`The 954 shell companies that have patents recorded against their names have an average of 8.5
`patents and 3.2 patent applications per company. Assuming that the other 242 shell companies
`contain unrecorded transactions, and applying these averages would yield another 2057 patents and
`774 applications. Adding these missing patents and applications to our totals would yield roughly
`10,000 patents and 3700 applications.23
`Intellectual Ventures also claims that it files roughly 500 applications per year and that it is now
`one of the top 50 US patent filers. The company is somewhat vague as to whether these 500
`applications comprise just those from its invention sessions or whether further filings24 from
`purchased portfolios are included in this total. In any event, given that patent applications publish 18
`months after filing, there should be roughly 750 presently unpublished patent applications as of May
`2011.25 Including unpublished applications keeps our estimate of US patents at

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket