throbber
EWE21 7/24/03 9:05 PM Page 469
`
`Chapter 21
`
`New Electronic Trading
`Systems in Foreign
`Exchange Markets
`
`Dagfinn Rime
`Norges Bank and Stockholm Institute for Financial Research
`
`I. Introduction
`II. The Structure of Foreign
`Exchange Markets
`A. Information and Agents
`B. Institutions
`C. Interbank Trading Options
`D. Transparency
`III. Direct Trading and Voice Brokers
`A. Dealer Behavior
`IV. Electronic Brokers
`A. Transparency
`B. Liquidity
`C. Transaction Costs
`
`D. The Future of Direct Trading
`and Voice Brokers
`E. Policy Implications
`V. Internet Trading
`A. The Emergence of Nonbank
`Customer Trading
`B. Internet Trading with Banks
`C. Possible Scenarios
`VI. Summary
`A. Web Sites on Trading and
`Networks
`References and Further Reading
`
`The foreign exchange market can be divided in two segments: the
`interbank market and the customer market. Two advances in trading
`technology, electronic brokers in the interbank market and internet
`trading for customers, have significantly changed the structure of the
`foreign exchange market. In this chapter, we explain the functioning
`of electronic brokers and internet trading and discuss the economic
`consequences. © 2003, Elsevier Science (USA).
`
`New Economy Handbook
`Copyright 2003, Elsevier Science (USA). All rights reserved.
`
`469
`
`GAIN CAPITAL - EXHIBIT 1014
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:05 PM Page 470
`
`470
`
`Rime
`
`Bid–ask spread Difference between the best buy price (ask) and best sell
`price (bid). The initiator of a trade buys at the ask and sells at the lower
`bid price. The spread is a measure of transaction costs. The buy price is
`also called the “offer.”
`Broker Brokers match dealers in the interbank market without being
`a party to the transactions themselves and without taking positions
`(cf. dealer).
`Call market A market where all traders trade at the same time when
`called upon.
`Counterparty credit risk The risk that the market participant on the other
`side of a transaction will default. Due to the large trade sizes in foreign
`exchange markets, credit risk is an important issue.
`Dealer A person employed by a bank whose primary business is entering
`into transactions on both sides of wholesale financial markets and
`seeking profits by taking risks in these markets (cf. broker).
`Dealer market Market where orders for execution pass to an inter-
`mediary (dealer) for execution.
`Interbank market The market where dealers trade exclusively with each
`other, either bilaterally or through brokers.
`Limit order Order to buy a specified quantity up to a maximum price or
`sell subject to a minimum price (cf. market order).
`Liquidity Characteristic of a market where transactions do not exces-
`sively move prices. It is also easy to have a trade effected quickly
`without a long search for counterparties (“immediacy”). Liquid markets
`usually have low bid–ask spreads, high volume, and (relatively) low
`volatility.
`Market maker Dealer ready to quote buy and sell prices upon request.
`The market maker provides immediacy (liquidity services) to the market
`and receives compensation through the spread. There is no formal oblig-
`ation to quote tight spreads; rather, market making is governed by
`reciprocity.
`Market order Order to buy (or sell) a specified quantity at the best pre-
`vailing price (cf. limit order).
`Order-driven market Market where prices are determined by an order
`execution algorithm from participants sending firm buy and sell orders,
`which are incorporated into the limit order book (cf. quote-driven or
`dealer market).
`Order flow Signed flow of transactions. The transaction is given a
`positive (negative) sign if the initiator of the transactions is buying
`(selling).
`Price discovery Determination of prices in a market. Incorporation of
`information into prices.
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 471
`
`21. E-Trading Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets
`
`471
`
`Quote-driven market Refers to a market where market makers post bid
`and ask quotes upon bilateral request. In the interbank market, these
`prices are on a take-it-or-leave-it basis (cf. order-driven market).
`Transparency Ability of market participants to observe trade information
`in a timely fashion.
`
`I. INTRODUCTION
`
`The 1990s gave us what might prove to be the two biggest changes in
`foreign exchange market structure since World War II: electronic brokers
`were introduced into the interbank market in 1992, and in the late 1990s
`the Internet became available as a trading channel for customers. What are
`the consequences for the market of these innovations? Is there any reason
`to believe that these technological developments have influenced the
`market in any significant way? Do not dealers in the foreign exchange
`market still fulfill their function as liquidity providers and aggregate infor-
`mation in their price setting? And, do not basic macroeconomic variables
`still drive exchange rates, irrespective of trading technology?
`In an ideal world with perfect information, these changes to the institu-
`tions of trading probably would not matter that much at the macro-
`economic level. In such a world, exchange rates would be determined by
`expectations regarding macroeconomic fundamentals like inflation, pro-
`ductivity growth, and interest rates. Exchange rates will be efficient asset
`prices when all market participants observe these fundamentals and agree
`on how they influence exchange rates. Furthermore, provision of liquidity
`would be much less risky than in a situation with imperfect information.
`However, as empirical evidence has shown all too clearly, models of an ideal
`world with perfect information do not hold, at least not for horizons shorter
`than a year or so.
`The microstructure approach to foreign exchange has made some
`promising steps toward solving some of these puzzles (see Lyons, 2001a).
`This approach differs from the traditional macroeconomic approach by
`allowing for imperfect information and heterogeneous agents and, thereby,
`leaving a role for trading institutions as such. In such a world, technologi-
`cal changes such as the introduction of electronic brokers and Internet
`trading may be significant because they change the structure of the market.
`A different market structure changes the game played between the
`market participants. This may influence information aggregation capabili-
`ties and incentives for liquidity provision and, thereby, different aspects of
`market quality like efficiency (price discovery), liquidity, and transac-
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 472
`
`472
`
`Rime
`
`tion costs. We are interested in understanding market structure because
`a well-functioning foreign exchange market is important for the macro-
`economy. This chapter considers the impact of technological advances on
`the foreign exchange market by focusing on these properties of market
`quality.
`The new economy and foreign exchange markets is a vast subject. We
`limit ourselves to the two major innovations in trading technology because
`trading institutions are an important part of a financial market’s structure.
`Furthermore, several studies show that trading is important for the
`determination of exchange rates. There is particular focus on a property
`of market structure called transparency, i.e., how much of the trading
`process market participants can observe. Because trading is an important
`determinant of exchange rates, observation of the trading process is
`important to enable dealers to set the “correct” exchange rates. On a more
`general level, transparency relates to how efficiently dealers can aggregate
`information.
`There are of course many other uses of information and communication
`technology (ICT) that have obviously influenced the markets that we do
`not address here. These include information providers such as Reuters
`and Bloomberg, computers’ calculation capabilities and the importance
`for option trading, and of course network technologies and computers in
`general. Two other technological innovations deserving special atten-
`tion that we do not consider are the newly started settlement service
`CLS Bank (Continuous Linked Settlement), which went live on September
`9, 2002, and the netting technology FXNet. The former links all participat-
`ing countries’ payment systems for real-time settlement. With such a
`system in place in 1974, the famous Bankhaus Herstatt default would
`never had happened. FXNet is a technology for netting out gross lia-
`bilities. Both are very important for the handling of counterparty credit
`risk.
`Sections II and III provide the background for the introduction of elec-
`tronic brokers and Internet trading. A brief description and history are
`given of the structure of the market prior to these innovations, followed by
`some considerations that dealers take into account in their trading. The
`trading institutions of the 1980s are referenced to clarify the differences.
`Section IV discusses electronic brokers, whereas Section V discusses Inter-
`net trading. Section VI provides a summary.
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 473
`
`21. E-Trading Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets
`
`473
`
`II. THE STRUCTURE OF FOREIGN EXCHANGE
`MARKETS
`
`Before we discuss electronic brokers and Internet trading, we need an
`overview of the general structure of the foreign exchange market so as to
`be able to understand the impact of these new trading institutions.Although
`electronic brokers were undoubtedly the most significant structural change
`in the 1990s, the general description given here is valid for the structure
`both before and after the introduction of electronic brokers. The reason is
`that brokers were present in the market before electronic brokers were
`introduced. The introduction of Internet trading, on the other hand, is still
`very recent, but it may prove to be the most significant structural shift of
`the first decade of the twenty-first century. This shift has the potential to
`overthrow the general structure of the market completely, a point that we
`come back to in Section V.
`
`A. INFORMATION AND AGENTS
`
`The foreign exchange market is the oldest and largest financial market
`in the world, with $1200 billion changing hands every day (April 2001).1
`These trades can be divided into interbank trades and customer trades, rep-
`resenting the two segments of the market. In the interbank market, trading
`is either direct (bilateral or taking place between dealers) or brokered
`(interdealer trades). Prior to the advent of the Internet, customers traded
`only with banks. We could have added customer-to-customer Internet-
`based trading sites, but we feel it is too early to pay them the same atten-
`tion as the three methods already mentioned (interbank, both direct and
`brokered, and customer–bank). In the 1990s, the market was often divided
`into three groups: customers, dealers, and brokers. However, as brokering
`becomes more and more electronic and also is open to customers through
`the Internet, we feel that it is more natural to focus on two main groups of
`traders: customers and dealers. The customers are the ultimate end-users of
`currency, and they typically make the largest single trades. Customers may
`be central banks, governments, importers and exporters of goods, and finan-
`cial institutions like hedge funds.
`Important characteristics of the foreign exchange market are that cus-
`tomers do not have access to the interbank market and that they do not
`trade with each other (except on the customer-to-customer sites mentioned
`
`1This number includes spot, forward, and swap volumes. In the following, we will focus on
`spot trading because spot is the most fundamental.
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 474
`
`474
`
`Rime
`
`earlier, which we return to later). The trading that takes place with cus-
`tomers is private information for the banks, and dealers stress the impor-
`tance of seeing customer flows. An interesting question is what kind of
`information this trading may reveal. For understanding the concept of infor-
`mation in the foreign exchange market, we need to add some details to what
`we mean by information, and Lyons (2002) suggests the description given
`in Table 1. The starting point is the expression of an asset price as the dis-
`counted expected value. Information may concern the expected value, the
`payoff-relevant part, or the discount rate (including the risk premium).
`In the upper left corner of Table 1, concentrated payoff-relevant infor-
`mation, or information on risk-neutral valuations, is the kind of private
`information that is typical in equity markets. In the case of foreign
`exchange,
`it probably does not constitute the main motivation for
`information-based trading. Changes in central banks’ interest rates are too
`infrequent and too shrouded in secrecy for private information about these
`rates to be a major driver of trading. However, private information about
`interventions is a possible candidate because central banks sometimes
`perform their interventions through particular banks. Bettina Peiers found
`that the exchange rate changes made by Deutsche Bank were leading the
`rates of other banks through rumors of interventions.
`Rather, Lyons (2002) suggests that it is the lower row in Table 1 that is
`most relevant in foreign exchange markets. The information that needs to
`be aggregated by the market is not concentrated on a few people, but rather
`dispersed among many. In their 2002 paper, Martin D. D. Evans and Lyons
`present a model where customer trading represents portfolio shifts and
`signals changes in risk premiums (information of the type in the lower right
`cell of Table 1). A risk premium arises as the compensation necessary to
`induce others to take the other side of the portfolio shift. This risk premium
`must be a permanent change in exchange rates because the new holders of
`currency must want to continue holding the currency.Their empirical results
`confirm this.
`
`Table 1
`Sources of Private Informationa
`
`Payoffs
`
`Discount rates
`
`Concentrated
`Dispersed
`
`Interest rate changes, interventions
`Expectations, information interpretation
`(“market sentiment”)
`
`Risk premiums (risk aversion,
`portfolio shift)
`
`aLyons (2002) suggests that information in the upper left corner is unlikely in foreign exchange
`markets and that the lower right corner is the more relevant.
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 475
`
`21. E-Trading Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets
`
`475
`
`We can also make an argument for the lower left cell. Because no model
`so far has proven to be the correct model for exchange rates, agents are
`likely to have different views on exchange rates. Customers’ trading counts
`the “votes” of the customers on where the exchange rate is heading. The
`hypothesis that information is dispersed has implications for optimal
`market structure: what kind of trading institutions are best fit for aggre-
`gating dispersed information? We come back to this in Section IV.
`
`B. INSTITUTIONS
`
`The market structure has not always been like the present structure.
`Prior to telecommunications, trading in foreign exchange markets could be
`described as a centralized call market. Trading in foreign exchange can be
`traced back to ancient times, when foreign exchange trading was a way to
`circumvent the ban on usury. In the sixteenth century, trading in foreign
`exchange occurred every third month at fairs in the Genoa area, each of
`which lasted for 8 days.2 However, telecommunications changed the general
`structure of the foreign exchange market, and it has been more or less unal-
`tered from the early 1930s up to the present.3 Drawing on the theory of the
`microstructure of financial markets, we can describe the current interbank
`foreign exchange market as follows:
`
`1. Trading is decentralized across several locations, as opposed to
`centralized on an exchange as is the case in many equity markets.
`2. There is continuous trading around the clock, as opposed to only
`when called upon as in a call market.
`3. There are several dealers that provide liquidity, as opposed to the
`specialist on the NYSE floor in earlier days, for example.
`4. Liquidity is both quote-driven, i.e., created by quoting bid and ask
`prices in response to trading initiatives (market making or dealer
`market), and order-driven, i.e., by entering limit orders with brokers
`(auction market).
`5. The market is relatively opaque, i.e., has low transparency compared
`with many equity markets.
`
`2The Genoa fairs lasted from 1532 to 1763 [see chapters by M. de Cecco in Newman et al.
`(1992)]. After this, Amsterdam and then London took over as the main location for currency
`trading.
`3It is difficult to find information on market structure from earlier periods. Several brokers
`started up in London in the 1930s with brokering over the telephone. Really active trading in
`foreign exchange, however, did not start until the mid-1960s, when regulations were eased in
`several European countries.
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 476
`
`476
`
`Rime
`
`The introduction of telecommunications allowed decentralized trade of
`the asset foreign exchange, as is most natural. Banks want to be present
`where the customers are, and because an exchange rate is the relative price
`of two assets from two different countries, it is natural to have a decen-
`tralized market. Given that customers are in different time zones and may
`have an interest in the same asset, say $, trading must also be continuous
`around the clock. Finally, given the geographical pattern of customers and
`the fact that several banks serve them, it is natural to have a number of
`dealers acting as liquidity providers in each currency pair. The decentral-
`ized structure also makes it very difficult to regulate foreign exchange
`trading, and the market structure has therefore evolved endogenously.
`These factors, together with the lack of regulatory disclosure requirements,
`mean that the foreign exchange markets are characterized by low
`transparency.
`All of this has economic consequences. Low transparency means that few
`of the dispersed signals that order flow may reveal will be observed by a
`single dealer. In a centralized call market, which is more transparent, infor-
`mation aggregation will typically be faster and more accurate. The lack of
`regulation is also important. Disclosure requirements are imposed on
`equity markets so that more trading, and hence more information, is
`observed by the market participants. As will be discussed later, the trading
`institutions also have implications for risk sharing.
`
`C. INTERBANK TRADING OPTIONS
`
`Foreign exchange trading typically follows a sequence. Customers’
`trading is the primary source of currency demand, and the sequence starts
`with a customer contacting her bank with a wish to trade (dealers never
`take the initiative). The bank acts as market maker and gives quotes to the
`customer. Customers do not have access to the interbank market, so an
`exporter cannot contact his counterparty or the counterparty’s bank
`directly. For a customer, trading with the counterparty directly involves
`credit risk, which could be handled more efficiently by a bank. A dealer in
`the bank then turns to the interbank market to cover the customer trade.
`Interbank trading actually accounts for between 60% and 80% of the total
`volume of foreign exchange trading, and we will come back to this issue in
`the next section because it is closely related to trading institutions.
`In the interbank market, the dealer has several options, as illustrated by
`the 2 ¥ 2 matrix in Table 2. In a multiple-dealer market, the dealer may
`choose to provide liquidity as a market maker and give quotes when con-
`tacted by other dealers (incoming trade), or he may trade on other market
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 477
`
`21. E-Trading Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets
`
`477
`
`Table 2
`Interbank Trading Optionsa
`
`Incoming (nonaggressor)
`
`Outgoing (aggressor)
`
`Direct
`
`Indirect
`
`Give quotes on request (market
`making)
`Dealer gives quote(s) to a broker
`(limit order)
`
`Trade at other dealers’ quotes
`(“taker”)
`Dealer trades at quotes given by a
`broker (market order)
`
`aA market maker gives quotes (buy and sell prices) on request from other dealers. The dealer
`that takes the initiative and asks for quotes is called the “aggressor.” Direct trading is bilat-
`eral trade over the D2000-1 computer system or the telephone. Indirect trading is trading
`through a broker, either a traditional “voice” broker (closed telephone network) or the elec-
`tronic brokers D2000-2 and EBS.
`
`makers’ quotes (outgoing trade). Because this is bilateral, it is often called
`direct trading. Furthermore, the interbank market is a hybrid market in the
`sense that liquidity can be provided both through making markets and by
`entering limit orders with brokers. The brokers announce the best bid and
`ask prices, and trading on these is a market order. Brokered trades are often
`called indirect trading.
`The information signal in trading is connected to the action of the most
`active part in the trade, often called the initiator or aggressor (outgoing
`trade). If the aggressor buys (sells), we say that it is a positive (negative)
`order flow, so order flow is just a transaction with a sign. How is this infor-
`mative? Think of the portfolio shift model of Evans and Lyons mentioned
`in the discussion of Table 1. If the aggressor buys, that could be because she
`is covering a position after a customer purchase (portfolio shift into that
`currency). Alternatively, think of the proposition that order flow reveals
`information about other dealers’ expectations. Then a purchase on behalf
`of the aggressor could be a signal, with noise, that the aggressor believes
`the currency is undervalued. In both cases, the positive order flow signals
`that the exchange rate should appreciate.
`
`D. TRANSPARENCY
`
`As mentioned earlier, transparency is low in foreign exchange markets
`compared to most equity markets. There are many forms of transparency:
`pretrade and posttrade transparency, transparency of prices or trades, and
`transparency with respect to whether the customers or only the dealers can
`observe the trading process. To start with the last of these, in the foreign
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 478
`
`478
`
`Rime
`
`exchange markets only the dealers can observe anything other than their
`own trading. The trades with customers that initiate the trading sequence
`are only observed by the bank that receives the order and, hence, are
`private information for the banks. In the interbank market, trades that are
`made directly between two dealers are only observed by the two dealers.
`The lack of disclosure requirements also ensures that these trades will not
`be observed by other dealers after the trade is made. Indirect trading is
`more transparent because the price and sign (buying or selling by the
`aggressor) of the last trades are observable. In this sense, trading through
`brokers is what determines the level of trade transparency. This level has
`evolved endogenously as a result of dealers’ indirect trading.
`Price transparency is higher than trade transparency, but until recently
`customers’ ability to see prices was less than that of dealers. However, com-
`pared to many equity markets with indirect trading, transparency is still low.
`In many equity markets a trader may be able to see the identity of the best
`bid and ask and often also a part of or the entire order book (all the other
`limit orders). In the case of a trade, both the size and the identity of the
`counterparties are revealed in many equity markets.
`
`III. DIRECT TRADING AND VOICE BROKERS
`
`In this section, we provide a further elaboration on the working of the
`interbank market prior to the electronic brokers by discussing how indirect
`and direct trading actually functions and affects dealers’ behavior. As men-
`tioned earlier, the trading institutions have been more or less unaltered for
`a long time, perhaps since the early 1930s when the first telephone brokers
`started. The composition of direct versus indirect trading has changed over
`time, however. For telephone brokers, the main innovation came in the
`1960s when brokers started operating through private telephone networks.
`These are installed free of charge in banks by brokers. The broker
`announces the best (limit order) bid and ask prices over intercoms at the
`dealers’ desk. If the dealer wants to trade at a limit order, i.e., submit a
`market order, he picks up the phone with the direct line and just says
`“mine” if he is buying (at the ask price) and “yours” if he is selling (at the
`bid price). The voice broker then knows which of the two announced prices
`at which he is trading. After a trade the broker announces the price and
`whether it was traded on the bid or the ask price. The size of the trade is
`not announced, but standard sizes are 1 and 5 million. This announcement
`was the only signal on marketwide order flow that the dealer received. Tele-
`phone brokers are often called voice brokers due to the announcements
`over intercom systems. Voice brokers were very popular up to the mid-
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 479
`
`21. E-Trading Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets
`
`479
`
`1980s at least. The main advantage for the dealers is that the dealer stays
`anonymous until the trade is made.
`Direct trading was made by telephone or telex in the 1970s. In February
`1981, Reuters introduced the Reuters Market Data Service (RMDS), which
`was like a bilateral bulletin board for conveying trading interest, for sub-
`sequent trading over the telephone. This system was replaced in 1987 by
`Reuters Dealing 2000-1, a closed network for bilateral electronic commu-
`nication. Although a system for electronic trading, it did not revolutionize
`the market. The D2000-1 is more like an advanced telephone and made the
`direct trading that used to take place over the telephone more efficient.
`D2000-1 quickly became the dominant tool for trading bilaterally. The
`dealers “chat” in much the same manner as with “instant messengers” on
`the Internet. Furthermore, trade tickets, needed to check trades and for set-
`tlement with counterparties, were sent automatically to the back office, and
`the dealer could trade faster and more efficiently with up to four conver-
`sations going simultaneously. With this system in place, direct trading
`started to take market share from voice brokers, and in the late 1980s to
`early 1990s, interbank volume was split 50/50 between direct trading and
`voice brokers.
`Table 3 reports some volume numbers from the United Kingdom, United
`States, and Japan, the three largest single markets, to help us get an idea of
`the size of the market. First we notice that in London alone there is trading
`for over $500 billion each day, down from over $630 in 1998. The foreign
`exchange market had grown rapidly from the collapse of Bretton Woods in
`the early 1970s, until the downturn in volume that we see from 1998. Total
`volume has decreased similarly, down to $1200 billion in 2001 from $1490
`billion in 1998. We will come back to the downturn in the next section. The
`increase in volume through the 1980s and 1990s was primarily driven by
`increased globalization, a dramatic increase in trading with customers in the
`late 1980s, and more banks entering the foreign exchange market.The intro-
`duction of D2000-1 might, however, have been a useful trading tool in this
`process. Not only could the system handle more trades simultaneously (the
`dealer could contact four market makers simultaneously) but D2000-1 also
`made cross-border trading easier. Voice brokers are quite regional. There
`are New York-based, London-based, Frankfurt-based, and Tokyo-based
`brokers, brokers serving Scandinavia, etc. Chatting electronically seems to
`be less hampered by borders.
`Notice also the high interbank share of foreign exchange volume in Table
`3. During the 1990s, the interbank share was between 60% and 80%,
`possibly at the high end for financial centers. This has been interpreted as
`speculative trading on the part of the banks, because it cannot be related
`to goods trading, etc. However, within this trading structure with a high
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 480
`
`480
`
`Rime
`
`Table 3
`Daily Trading Volumesa
`
`United Kingdom
`
`United States
`
`Japan
`
`Volume Share (%) Volume Share (%) Volume Share (%)
`
`2001 Total volume
`Total interbank
`Total spot
`
`1998 Total volume
`Total interbank
`Total spot
`
`1995 Total volume
`Total interbank
`Total spot
`
`1992 Total volume
`Total interbank
`Total spot
`
`1989 Total volume
`Total interbank
`Total spot
`
`1986 Total volume
`Total interbank
`Total spot
`
`504
`341
`151
`
`637
`530
`217
`
`464
`349
`186
`
`290
`230
`148
`
`184
`161
`119
`
`90
`82
`66
`
`68
`30
`
`83
`34
`
`75
`40
`
`79
`51
`
`88
`65
`
`91
`55
`
`254
`143
`104
`
`351
`171
`148
`
`244
`138
`134
`
`167
`122
`95
`
`125
`116
`81
`
`59
`54
`34
`
`56
`41
`
`49
`42
`
`57
`55
`
`73
`57
`
`93
`65
`
`93
`42
`
`147
`123
`37
`
`136
`109
`57
`
`161
`118
`55
`
`120
`92
`48
`
`111
`78
`46
`
`48
`32
`19
`
`83
`25
`
`80
`42
`
`74
`34
`
`76
`40
`
`70
`41
`
`67
`41
`
`aSource: Average daily volumes as reported in BIS (1990, 1993, 1996, 1999, 2002). All volumes
`are corrected for local double-counting. Total volume and total interbank volume in each
`country is the sum of spot, forward, and swap volumes in the overall and interbank markets,
`respectively. Interbank share and spot share are calculated as the share of total interbank
`volume.
`
`share of direct trading, a high interbank share may be the result of risk
`sharing between the banks after receiving large customer orders. Imagine
`that a large customer order, for example €100 million, ends up at the desk
`of an interbank dealer. Let us assume that the dealer wants to get rid of it.
`The dealer has relationships with 10 other dealers (market makers) and
`sells €10 million to each through (outgoing) direct trading. For the sake of
`the argument, assume that none of these dealers are particularly interested
`in the position. They accept the trade because they get compensation
`through the bid–ask spread (incoming trade on their behalf). Each of them
`turns to two of their contacts and sells €5 million to each. The interbank
`volume is now €200 million, and it continues to grow. The €5 million that
`20 dealers have received are sold to other dealers again, and the volume
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 481
`
`21. E-Trading Systems in Foreign Exchange Markets
`
`481
`
`reaches €300 million! The customer trade is passed on like a “hot potato.”
`When the process comes to an end, all dealers, including our initial dealer,
`hold a share of the initial customer order. Large interbank trading flows
`could, in other words, be a consequence of a market structure with a high
`share of direct trading.
`
`A. DEALER BEHAVIOR
`
`How do the dealers behave in such a hybrid market? We can use the
`dealer studied by Lyons in 1992 (see Lyons, 2001a) as an example of how
`a market maker works. The dealer operated as a market maker in a New
`York investment bank in 1992 and traded almost entirely by giving quotes
`on the D2000-1 system (market making e.g., direct incoming trading).
`A market maker sets bid and ask prices, the difference being the spread
`and the midpoint typically being her expectation. The spread is a function
`of three components: (i) adverse selection protection; (ii) risk management;
`and (iii) order processing costs and rents. To discourage informed traders
`and make money from the uninformed (she always loses to the better
`informed), the market maker increases the spread with trade size, hence,
`making it more expensive to trade. Similarly, the spread increases with
`size as compensation for taking on the risk in the trade. The part of the
`spread due to order processing costs and rents is usually modeled as a
`constant.
`The spread is measured in “pips,” with one pip being the fourth decimal
`in most exchange rates (the fifth in £ exchange rates). The median spread
`for the dmark/$ dealer studied by Lyons (2001a) was three pips, and the
`median trade size was $3 million. Geir Bjønnes and Dagfinn Rime find, in
`similar data for direct trading from 1998, a median spread of two pips, with
`a median trade size of $1 million. The spread was relatively constant up to
`$5 million. This may seem like a tiny transaction cost. If the dmark/$ was
`trading at 1.8, then a two-pip spread is only slightly more than one basis
`point (1%/100), and buying $1 million would cost approximately $55. When
`one realizes that, in April 1998, dmark/$ was traded for almost $100 billion
`daily in the interbank market alone (corrected for double counting), the
`risk sharing process mentioned earlier becomes quite expensive ($5.5
`million daily in interbank dmark/$ trading alone).
`The dealer that makes the contact (aggressor) asks for bid and ask prices
`for a given size without revealing his trading intentions. In “direct” trading,
`market makers are expected to give tight quotes promptly on request, and
`the aggressor is similarly expected to reply quickly. The quotes are on a
`take-it-or-leave-it basis. If there is a trade, the server analyzes the conver-
`
`

`

`EWE21 7/24/03 9:06 PM Page 482

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket