throbber
Dr)wm’()aded_fi~0:rr U1-'/I-.")ARE, {he m.s‘.'imrirJ;1a! repavfrory Qfrlre Um'versir_v (gfArn.s'rcm’arr1 (Ur/U
`Imp.‘//hdf. handle. net/1'1 245/2. 85961
`
`Fiie ID
`Filename
`Version
`
`uvapub:85961
`Thesis
`unknown
`
`SOURCE (OR PART OF THE FOLLOWING SOURCE):
`Type
`PhD thesis
`Title
`The world's first stock exchange: how the Amsterdam market for Dutch
`East India Company shares became a modern securities market, 1602-1700
`L.O. Petram
`FGw: Instituut voor Cultuur en Geschiedenis (ICG)
`2011
`
`Author(s)
`Faculty
`Year
`
`FULL BIBLIOGRAPHIC DETAILS:
`
`http://hd1.hand1e.net/1 1245/1.342701
`
`( '0,-J}-'r‘ig.*1r
`
`H is not permmed :0 dcmufload or Iafi;m=c:rd/disrribure the rexr or per.’ qff! wrmrmr the canyon.’ qfflre a.=r.'h0r'{sJ and/or
`c‘up_l-‘Hghf J'1m*de:'(.v). umerrhanfi.-r.m'.‘cn3rpe::-;unae’, mdividrrai use. :.-m’e.s:s- fire work ."..~' rmderan open cwmznr !:'r.-encr: (Like
`('rear:'vc ('mnmrm.\‘)_
`
`:'."\'A-!.)AR.*:' is :1 .\-<’.v1'.*'r.-0 ;m:n':'derJ by the h'.’mrr_1‘ qfrfw Um'~-'er:s'."r_1‘ qf}1m.mem':r:u (.F:Ir_r:.‘»¢'?km.*.:rI’rI. HI)
`1'_vn;.zeda R’: 2!’) I4- I I -2} J
`
`1
`
`IBG LLC ET AL. - EXHIBIT 1015 PART 1
`
`1
`
`IBG LLC ET AL. - EXHIBIT 1015 PART 1
`
`

`
`THE WORLD’S FIRST STOCK EXCHANGE
`
`How the Amsterdam market for Dutch East India Company
`
`shares became a modern securities market, 1602-1700
`
`Lodewijk Petram
`
`2
`
`

`
`Frontcover: Gerrit Adriaensz. Berckheyde, Town hall on Dam Square (1672), detail,
`Rijksmuscum Amsterdam
`
`3
`
`

`
`THE WORLD’S FIRST STOCK EXCHANGE
`
`How the Amsterdam market for Dutch East India Company
`
`shares became a modern securities market, 1602-1700
`
`ACADEMISCH PROEFSCHRIFT
`
`ter verkrijgillg van de graad van doctor
`aan de Universiteit van Amsterdam
`
`op gezag van de Rector Magnificus
`prof. dr. D.C. van den Boom
`ten overslaan van een door het College Voor promoties ingestelde
`commissie, in het openbaar te verdedjgen in de Aula der Unive rsiteit
`
`op vrijdag 28jar1uar“i 201 1, to 13.00 uur
`
`door
`
`Lodewijk Otto Petram
`
`gcborcn Le Apeldoom
`
`4
`
`

`
`5
`
`

`
`CONTENTS
`
`List of figures
`
`List of tables
`
`List of maps
`
`List of abbreviations
`
`Introduction
`
`Context, nistoriograptgy and ttieog
`Scope and structure
`Sources
`
`Part I - Taking the measure of the market
`
`1
`
`A chronology of the market
`Introduction
`
`I 602 - The suoscrifition
`1 607 - Wee emergence ofa derivatives market
`I 609- I0 - Isaac to Maire
`I 609— I8 First dividend distrio-utions
`
`I 61' 1' - Evccfzange building
`I 622 - Wee relation between tfie company and its snareftotders
`t630s and I 6405 -- Inteimediation and a changing composition oft/ze trading community
`I 6605 - Trading ctubs and rescontre
`Cono:’n.riont
`
`2
`
`Long-term developments
`Introduction
`
`ft/{arket activity
`Number iftraders
`Snare price and dividends
`Divergent a’eoetopments‘.' Amsterdam and penptierat rnarkets‘
`Conctusions
`
`VII
`
`VIII
`
`VIII
`
`IX
`
`1
`
`2
`6
`9
`
`17
`1 7
`
`I 7
`20
`24
`28
`
`30
`32
`36
`45
`:32
`
`59
`5.9
`
`59
`64
`65
`68
`7 4
`
`6
`
`

`
`Part II — The organization of the market
`
`3 Contract enforcement
`
`Introduction
`
`Ttte tegoifiomework
`Private enflorcernent mecnonisrn
`Conclusions
`
`Appendix - Snort snrnrnoagv ofconrt cases
`
`4
`
`Risk seeking and risk mitigation
`Introduction
`
`Connterpory risk
`Poryotio risk
`Conclusions
`
`5
`
`Information
`Introduction
`
`Investors’ injorrnntion needs in t/tejirst decode the sezrenteent/2 centttfjr
`Market reactions to irfinnotion
`Wee infimnotion networks ofC.‘/tr.-istion nndjeooislt snore traders
`Conclusions
`
`Conclusions
`
`Epilogue — Reassessing Corgfizsion de coryilsiones
`
`Summary (in Dutch)
`
`Appendices
`Appendix A - Montnb snore price Arnsterdorn chamber !-''O(;; 1' 602-1’ 693
`Appendix B - Dividend distributions I-‘()(:, I602} 700
`Appendix C - Glossary
`
`Acknowledgements
`
`Bibliography
`Prirnop sources
`Pubtisited primary sources
`Secondary Eiteroture
`
`Index of names and places
`
`91
`.92’
`97
`107
`114
`I15
`
`118
`H8
`I20
`I34
`I45
`
`148
`I48
`I50
`
`156
`I65
`175
`
`180
`
`186
`
`190
`
`196
`I96
`204
`206
`
`210
`
`211
`21'}
`21'}
`213
`
`219
`
`VI
`
`7
`
`

`
`LIST OF FIGURES
`
`Figure 1.1 Forward contract used in a transaction between V'\='i11ern Muijlman and
`Philips de Bacher, 2 September 1644.
`Figure 1.2 Amsterdam Exchange of Hendrick de Keyser, etching by C._]. Visscher
`(1612)
`Figure 1.3 Amsterdam Exchange of Hendrick dc Keyscr, interior, painting byjob
`Adriaensz. Berckheyde (between 1670 and 1690)
`Figure 2.1 5-day period share transfers, \-’OC Amsterdam chamber, 1609
`Figure 2.2 5-day period share transfers, \-"()C Amsterdam chamber, 1639
`Figure 2.3 5-day period share transfers, \-’(')C Amsterdam chamber, 1667
`Figure 2.4 5-day period share transfers, \-'OC Amsterdam chamber, 1672
`Figure 2.5 5-day period share transfers, \-‘QC: Amsterdam chamber, 1688
`Figure 2.6 Monthly ‘.»’0(‘: share price, Amsterdam chamber, September 1602 -
`February 1698. Missing values derived from linear interpolation.
`Figure 2.7 Monthly ‘JOC share price, Amsterdam chamber, September 1602 -
`February 1693
`Figure 2.9 Yearly high-low-average \-'(')C share price, Amsterdam chamber, 1602-
`1698
`
`54
`
`55
`
`56
`76
`77
`78
`
`79
`80
`
`81
`
`82
`
`83
`
`Figure 2. 10 Yearly dividends as a percentage of the nominal value of \-'OC shares,
`1620-1699
`
`Figure 2.12 Dividend as a percentage of market value, 1620-1697
`Figure 2.13 Real dividend and \-'OC share price, 1630-98
`Figure 2. 14 Share price data of the Amsterdam, Middelburg, Enkhuizen and Hoorn
`87
`chambers of the VOC, 1611-1685
`146
`147
`178
`179
`
`Figure /-1. 1 Forward and repo transactions represented in diagram form
`Figure 4.2 Size of loans granted on shares pledged as collateral, 1649-1688
`Figure 5.1 \-’(_)C share price, 7July 1671
`31 December 1672
`Figure 5.2 voc: share price, Gjanuary 1688 - 22 November 1688
`
`84
`85
`86
`
`VII
`
`8
`
`

`
`LIST OF TABLES
`
`Table 1.1 Spot transactions of Christoffel andjan Raphoen, 1626-42
`Table 2.1 Total number of shareholders’ accounts, Amsterdam chamber \-'00, 1602
`and 1679-1695; number of active accounts and share transfers, 1609, 1639,
`1667, 167’? and 1688
`
`38
`
`64
`
`Table 2.2 Share price data of the Middelburg, Enkhuizen, and Hoorn chambers of
`the \-'00
`
`75
`
`Table 3.1 Court of Holland, Extended sentences
`Table 3.2 Court ofl-lolland, Case files
`
`High Council, Extended sentences
`Table
`Table 4.1 Estimated costs ofjeronimus Velters’ forward and repo transactions
`
`1 15
`l 17
`
`1 17
`125
`
`LIST OF MAPS
`
`Map 1.1 Main share trade locations in the first decade of the seventeenth century
`Map 1.2 Main share trade locations after the opening of the Exchange (161 1)
`
`57
`58
`
`VIII
`
`9
`
`

`
`LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
`
`BT
`
`Bibliotheca Thysiana, Leyden
`
`I).-\S
`
`_].R. Bruijn, F.S. Gaastra and I. Sel16lI'er, 1)utd:—Asia!ic s‘kz}Jping in the 37!}: and
`
`18% centzmfes (3 vols., The Hague 1979-87).
`
`I-:I(1:
`
`NA
`
`PA
`
`PIG
`
`RAU
`
`English East India Company
`
`Nationaal Archief, The Hague
`
`Persmuseum Amsterdam
`
`Portugees-Israélitische Gemeente
`
`Het Utrechts Archief
`
`SAA
`
`Stadsarchief Amsterdam
`
`\-"'00
`
`Verenigde Oost-Indisehe Cornpagnie
`
`WIC
`
`\Nest-Indisclle Compagnie
`
`_Nbte on curremgy
`
`The Dutch currency, the guilder (f), was divided into 20 stzzimzs; each swine?‘ was sub-
`
`divided into 16 penmfngm. In addition to guilders, the Dutch also used pounds Flemish
`
`[pVl). The nominal value of \-'()(I shares was, for example, often expressed in pounds
`
`Flemish. One pound Flemish equaled six guilders. To make currelltty fiyres more
`
`easily comprehensible,
`CC DIS.
`
`I have converted everything into guilders divided into 100
`
`10
`
`IX
`
`10
`
`

`
`11
`
`11
`
`

`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`‘This little game could bring in more money than contracting charter parties for ships
`
`bound for England’, wrote Rodrigo Dias Henriques to Manuel Levy Duarte on 1 No-
`
`vember 1691.‘ Dias Henriques was referring to the ‘game’ of trading shares of the
`
`Dutch East India Company (Verenigde Oost-Indische Compagnie,
`
`\-'OC, founded
`
`1602) and its derivatives* on the Amsterdam securities market. He acted as exchange
`
`agent for Levy Duarte and performed a high number of transactions on his account.
`
`The most notable feature of the exchange dealings of these Portuguese Jewish mer-
`
`chants was that they consisted solely of very swift trades; Dias I-Ienriques made sure to
`
`always settle the transactions within a few days or a fortnight at most. He actively
`
`spec.ulated on short-term share price* movements, while at the same time making sure
`
`that his portfolio did not become too risky
`
`and,judging by his quote, he was rather
`
`good at it. Dias Henriques could perform these swift dealings because by the end of
`
`the seventeenth century, a very active secondary market* for securities existed in Am-
`
`sterdam.
`
`Modern securities markets have two functions: price discovery* and the provi-
`
`sion of liquidity“. The interaction of traders in the marketplace, in other words, de-
`
`termines the price of the assets that are traded on the market. The liquidity function
`
`means that as a result of the concentration of traders in the marketplace, traders can
`
`easily buy or sell assets. Straightforward as these market functions may seem, they play
`
`a very important roie for investors: they allow investors to reallocate their asset hold-
`
`ings at low cost, enabling them to manage their financial risks according to their per-
`
`sonal preferences.9 Securities markets thus provide major advantages to investors.
`
`The secondary market for VOC shares became the first securities market in his-
`
`tory that provided these advantages to investors. Hence it was in seventeenth-century
`
`Amsterdam that ‘the global securities market began to take on its modern form’.3 Us-
`
`ing hitherto unexplored source material from the archives of the V()C1,judicial institu-
`
`tions of the Dutch Republic and merchants who were active on the securities market,
`
`' Dias Henriques to Levy Duarte. l l\'-ovember l69 l, .‘-l.-\.-'\, PIG, inv. nr. 677. pp. 897-8.
`‘ Words market with an asterisk {*} are further explained in Appendix C - Glossary.
`'3 Maureen O’l-lara, ‘Presidential address: Liquidity and price discovery’, jmtrnrrt’ rgffinmtrt.’ 58 (2003)
`1335- I354-, there 1335.
`3 R-anald C. M iehie, 'T'.=r giulm-I .s‘ecmr'tt}r.s' marfirct.‘ a r':i.n!a1_”}‘ (Oxford 2006) 26.
`
`12
`
`12
`
`

`
`this book analyzes how the secondary market for \--'0(: shares could develop into the
`
`world’s first modern securities market.
`
`Context, historiograpfy and tlteopv
`
`How the secondary market for \-'OC shares started off in the first decade of the seven-
`
`teenth century is well known} In 1602, the States General of the Dutch Republic
`
`granted the VOC a charter for a period of 21 years, with the provision that an interim
`
`liquidation would follow after ten years.-"’ Inhabitants of the Dutch Republic were
`
`called upon to invest in the new company. The \-'OC thus became a privately-owned
`
`company in which the authorities of the Dutch Republic had a large say. The capital
`
`subscription was a great success: in Amsterdam alone, 1143 investors signed up for
`
`f3,679,9l5.‘5 According to a clause on the first page of the subscription book of the
`
`\-'0C, shareholders could transfer their shares to a third party. On this same page, the
`
`procedure for registering share transfers was laid down:
`
`the buyer and the seller
`
`should go to the East India house where the bookkeeper, after two company directors
`
`had approved the transfer, transferred the share from the seller’s to the huyer’s ac-
`
`count in the capital book?
`
`These clear rules for ownership and transfer of ownership reduced investors’
`
`hesitancy about trading the valuable shares that existed only on paper. Secondary
`
`market trading therefore took a start immediately after the subscription books were
`
`closedfi‘ However, the real incentive to trade shares emerged later. The directors of
`
`the VOC: did not liquidate the company after ten years and at the end of the first char-
`
`ter, in 1623, they requested a prolongation of the charter, which the States General
`
`"f See, particularly: Oscar Gelderhlom and _]oost Junker, ‘Completing a Iinancial revolution: '1‘ht=-. Ii-
`nance of the Dutcli East India trade and the rise of the Amsterdam capital market, 159.’)-l6li?’, 771:’
`jimmrtf ryfrcnitomir a":irtn;}' 64 [2(}U4} 641-[$72.
`3 For a general account ofllte founding oflhe \'0(:, see:_].:\. van der Chijs, (£es'ci::i*(:’mis' (fir 5'ticf1fing can dz
`Iéurm {gale 0.1. C'am_tmgnie an o'er are-niregelert z-rm dc ..-Nhferfrrrtdsr.-':e' regertngr beirqflienrie dc! ma rt up Oasi—Inciiéi i'L-'€fJi‘t" (ran
`daze .i'tir.r‘n'irtg uoorrgfgirtgmt [Leyden i857}. This brink also contains a transcription -of the 1602 charter. The
`text ofthe first charter can also be found online: l1ttp://wwwxocsitc.nl/geschiedenis/octrooi.l1tml An
`English translation is also online available:
`http:/ /www.ztustralia0I1thcma]).ot'g.au /contcnt/vicw/ 50/ 59
`'3 The total capital stock of the \'0(: amounted to f6,429,588; Middelburg contributed fl,30(},405
`{2U".r’u]I, Enkhuiaen [54-0,000 (8%), Delft f4-59,41-U0 {7%}, Hoorn f§26fi,86B (4”fa‘,' and Rotterdam
`fl ?3,0(lU (3%): Henk den Heijer, Dr geadrooieerale rnt::])agnir.' (fr VOC en (fr WK.‘ (IE5 t-'onri'n_fM:'.r a-mt ale’ nrtarttloze
`:.IertnnoLtr:fmp [_De\-‘enter 2005] (ii. According to the historical purchasing power calculator of the Interna-
`tional Institute of Social History in Arnsterdani
`l1ttp:/ /www.iisg.nl/ hpw/ calculate.php), the value
`of the 1602 subscription would amount to almost CIUU million today.
`7 A facsimile and transcript of the first page of the subscription book can be found in:_].G. van Dillen,
`Hr! rltmftlt’ rtrtrt(t’e.el':‘iattr2'rstr.=agf.rIr:' van (fr Ki?!P1PJ'_’fHi.h'}."?'dfl?ft d8?‘ On.rt—Btdf.rr:’n? Corttpngriie [The Hague 1958) 105-6.
`3 Gelderblom 2tt](lJ0l1l<t'.l', ‘Completing’.
`
`13
`
`13
`
`

`
`granted. Again, no intermediate liquidation took place. Consequently,
`
`the capital
`
`stoek* of the VOC became defects fixed.“ In the end, the company would stay in busi-
`
`ness for almost two centuries and the capital stock remained fixed during the entire
`
`period. Since investors generally do not want their money to be locked up for that a
`
`long period of time, they used the secondary market to sell their shareholdings to a
`
`third party.
`
`The fixed capital stock of the VOC was unique. Shipping companies in late-
`
`medieval Italy and, from the mid-sixteenth century onwards, also in England and the
`
`Low Countries were often equity*-financed, but these companies were always liqui-
`
`dated after a single expedition to the destination. The same went for the Vom'.cemf3ag-
`
`ntkéa, the predecessors of the \-*'OC that had equipped expeditions to the East Indies
`
`from 1594 onwards. The proceeds of the liquidation were divided among the inves-
`
`tors. In many cases, the company was reestablished immediately after liquidation and
`
`participants were given the opportunity to reinvest their money in the new partner-
`
`ship. Consequently, there was little need for secondary market trading, because after
`
`liquidation, investors could decide not to reinvest. Investors knew that they could al-
`
`ways get their money back within a few years’ time. '0 Likewise, it took until the end of
`
`the seventeenth century before a secondary market for shares emerged in England."
`
`Before that time, there were no joint-stock companies with a sufficiently large fixed
`
`capital to get the development of a securities market going.” The capital stock of the
`
`English East India Company (F.I(‘.:, founded 1600], for example, only became fixed in
`
`H357’. Before that time, the EIC repeatedly issued new stock to fund its fleets; the EIC
`
`was thus basically a series of separate companies that worked together as the LZIC. '3
`
`Remarkably, already in the later Middle Ages, secondary markets for public
`
`debt had emerged in Italian city states. Venice, Genoa and Florence were the first
`
`‘-' Den Hcijcr, De gm.r.‘tmnia’rd.<.° rnntpagnie, 59, 63.
`"' Oscar Gclderblom, Abe dejong a:1(l_]oos1Jo11ke1', “An Admiralty for Asia. Isaac le Maire and con-
`flicting conceptions about the corporate governance of the \‘(')(.E’, in: Jonathan G.S. Koppell (ed.), Tar
`an'gim gf_r;‘rareJ':o!rt'er rm't*nrar)r(Basi11gstoke, forthcoming 201 I].
`” Anne L. Murphy, The oiigias r_JfEngIisfi_finanrirtI m(tr'!m‘s. Imwstmem‘ and rfircrtlatian effort’ the .S‘ottt:‘.= Sm Babble
`{Cambridge 2009).
`'3 Ron Harris,
`Inri:t5tn}t£iz:}t_g r':}:rg!is!.= Eat:-2‘ erttrrfireriettrsfifi and f)t¢‘s‘ftt€35 or;gani.zr:ti:2n,
`2000}ll7-8,120-1,121
`'5 The fixed capital stock of the Ial(I in 1657 amounted to £793,782. W.R. Scott, The r:m.i!itttIt'or.' and
`fimimfr ryfEngft.rl1,
`.S‘rn££i.w)‘: and Irisizjnint-stark rorttpaniers to 1720 ll (.'nn:,(:arzierfl2rfiare{gn trade. rritanization, _fi.c:‘iirz_g
`and mining (Cambridge l9l2} I29, I92. Nlichiel de jongh, ‘De ontwikkeling van zeggeiischapsrecliten
`van aandeelhouclcrs in dc 1?" en 18" ceuw’, l-I/arking paper [200‘:l). At the exchange rate of 1654 (the I65?
`rate is unavailable), fi793,?82 equaled approximatclyf8,25[l,00(}: N.W. Posthumus, .Nera’e:'lr:nrfsc!ie prjsger
`.rrIti.r3ds;zi.r 1: (}oe’de?rr’n,{J:ijze;t up do:
`.'5mr.r t-‘rm Am.r£erzi'an: 158.‘I—}9)' 4.
`l'l"i.rs£fI'rne::rrrri £2 zlmmidnrn }6‘09—19}-F Ley-
`den l9~"r3) 592.
`
`!72{}—irfH4 (New York
`
`14
`
`14
`
`

`
`states to consolidate their public debt - a revolution in public finance, because it eased
`
`the process of underwriting new debt issues.” Venice, for example, consolidated all its
`
`outstanding debt in a so-called moms in 1262. The original obligations were converted
`
`into shares in the invites and investors could subsequently transfer the title to these
`
`shares by way of assignment. Secondary markets came into being, but these markets
`
`did not have the characteristics of a free market, since new loans were often forced
`
`loans. Hence, the. decision to invest was not taken by the investors themselves. tVIoreo-
`
`ver, the number of transfers typically rose when a new forced loan was announced,
`
`which indicates that some shareholders were forced to dump their shares on the sec-
`
`ondary market to get the liqttidity needed to pay for the upcoming debt issue.” This
`
`innovation in public finance failed to spread to other parts of Europe, however. In the
`
`Low Countries, the provinces kept issuing short—term debt and it would take until at
`
`least 1672 before seeondaiy trade of any significance took place in government debt in
`
`the Dutch Republic.“‘ The English government recognized the advantages of secon-
`
`dary market trading in the early eighteenth century. It started to use the secondary
`
`market to sell its debt in transferable annuity obligations in the 17205.”
`
`This short overview has identified the factors that led to the emergence ofa
`
`secondary market for VOC: shares in the Dutch Republic. Very little is known about
`
`the subsequent development of the market, however. Smith studied the trade in de-
`
`rivatives, focusing on official regulations and pamphlets that addressed the share
`
`trade, and Gelderhlom and jonker discussed the history of derivatives trading on the
`
`Amsterdam exchange from 1550 to 1650, mentioning the emergence of several types
`
`of derivatives and analyzing similarities and differences in the trade in equity deriva-
`
`tives and forward* contracts that were used in the grain trade.'8 Apart from these
`
`"' Sec, particularly: Reinhold CI. .\»lueiler, T719 Venetian along}-' ntarket.‘ banks. firtrtirs, and If!» pitblir debt,
`I500 {Baltimore 1997).
`'5Julius Kirshner, ‘Encumhering private claims to public debt in renaissance Florence’, in: Vito Pier-
`giovanni {ed.), Tilt»? growth’: rflifte: brrml as iasti£1:a'n:.= and the dwelnprnent ry"inom_r}'—busines.r Ina: (Berlin 1993} 19-76.
`Meir Kohn, ‘The capital market before l60[l’, Da.='tmottth C'rJll'ege tonrlrirrg paper nr. 99-06 (1999) 10-1 1.
`'”Jamcs D. Tracy, Ajinartrial reanltstion in the Hab.s‘fmi;g _-’\:'}:t:’:e?rt'rtii(t’.r.' Return and r.m£em'er5 in Mt‘ rnmty r3fHnl!aitrt',
`I515-15623 {Berkeley 1985). Oscar Gelderblom and _]oosI_]or1ke1', ‘A conditional miracle. 'l'l1e market
`forces that shaped Holland's public debt management’, l'l"nrki.=.=g paper (2010) 2] , ‘.24-7.
`'7 Larry Neal, '17:? nits’ rgffirtaitriml rrI,;‘)i!ali'sr:t.' tittemalinnal crtfrital ntrmlz’!s in tire Age rfffltrtson {Cambridge 1990)
`I0.
`
`)'2'‘(){)—
`
`'” V1.1’ Smith, Tijrl-(_rj?aircs' in g,-‘fé.-:.-181: arm (is Ant.s'fer(Ia3n_\'ckr baits: (The Hague I919). Oscar Gelderblom
`and Joost jonlter, ‘Amsterclann as the cradle of modern Futures and options trading, 1550-1650’, in:
`‘William N. Goctzmann and K. Geert Rouwenhorst {eds}, 7719 m'gim' ryfisalttr: .'.-'tafimnt‘t'rtl irtnn:.'rt!ion.r Ilia!
`rr'm!m" modern capital mar:l'£;‘.r {Oxford 2005} l89-205. The article ‘Completing’, by the same authors, has
`been mentioned above. This article liocused on the funding ofliast India trade in the Dutch Republic
`
`15
`
`15
`
`

`
`studies, most economic historians merely marveled at the sophistication of the market
`
`in the late seventeenth century. They used Josseph de la Vega’s high-flown description
`
`of the share trade in Cbigfizsién de corgfiuioaes, the famous account of the share market
`
`dating from 1688'“, as a starting point for their work?“ Others tried to catch the sig-
`
`nificance of the market in very general phrases. Barbour, for example, wrote that
`
`‘Amsterdam gave [existing financial instruments] more precise formulation, greater
`
`flexibility and extension, and used them effectively over a wider field.’2' E-raudel’s in-
`
`terpretation of the financial developments in Amsterdam was that ‘ce qui est nouveau
`
`it Amsterdam, c’est le volume, la iluidité, la publicité, la liberté speculative des transac-
`
`tions. Lejeu s’y méle de facon frénétique, le jeu pour le jeu."-3'-3-' Superficial as these ob-
`
`servations may seem, they touch upon some very important aspects of the market.
`
`The flexibility and enhanced formulation of the financial instruments meant that in-
`
`vestors could use them to manage their financial risks. Moreover, the market could
`
`fulfill its core functions price discovery and liquidity only because of the increase in
`
`trading activity. This raises the questions which factors led to the sophistication of
`
`financial instruments in Amsterdam? And what caused trading activity to increase on
`
`the Amsterdam market?
`
`In this book, the development of the market will be examined from an institu-
`
`tional perspective. In the most widely used definition, institutions ‘are the rules of the
`
`game in a society or, more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape
`
`human interaction.”-" Institutions consist of formal and informal rules. Informal rules
`
`are not enforceable by law; they mostly depend on social sanctions for their enforce-
`
`ment. Formal institutions, such as laws and official regulations, are enforced by the
`
`and argued that the emergence ofa. secondary market for shares completed the linancial revolution of
`the sixteenth centLln_,-‘, as has been advanced by James D. Tracy: Tracy, A ffmintirti resniittion.
`"' Dutch translation of'De la V’ega’s work, with a good introduction by .\'I.F._]. Smithzjosseph Penso de
`la Vega, Corfir.rio'n dr co:gfii.s‘ianr.r (1688), \I.F,]. Smith [_ed.} (The Hague 1939). The best Eiiglish (abridged)
`(‘(‘liIl0l’1I_IOSS(?p h Penso de la Vega, Chrgfitrinri dc .-:nnftm'orie’.r b '_}n.re];!t de la Vega I638. Pa-i'!I'on5 derirnptitre ryfltte
`Am.ri'erdrIm Stork Errhangc (1688) Hermann Kellenbenz ed. Cambridge I957}.
`3"’ Jonathan Israel, amongst others, relies heavily on De la Vega, for example in: Jonathan I. Israel,
`jews and the stock exchange: the Amsterdam Iinaneial crash of 1688’, in: idem (ed.},
`.’).='a.ipt=rr:.a‘ at-itiitir a
`dfn.rpera.']eLt=5, (I9-‘pin-j’eit!5 arm’ the world niaritiine rnipir.r.i' (}.‘340-I740) {Leyden 2002) 4-Ll-9-87. Also: Charles
`Wilson, Aitgt'o—1)::¢‘o’t rarnnzrirr andfinanrr in the mlgirteeiitit t‘8.’iilw_'}' (Cambridge I941, reprinted in 1966). Geof-
`frey Poitras, 772:’ er.-rt’;-‘
`.’u'stn:_;: nJ(:finrutria! rmiiomiee,
`f478—}776.'finm mrmiterruzt’ rtritftfitefft.‘ to lg)?! nnit:u't£er and
`join! .nfon|'r.i' {Cllieltenliain 2000) 3].’), 385-7.
`1” Violet Barbour, C'(t,bitm't'5m in Am.r£em’am in the m'rn!.«.>mt:‘z rentmy {Baltimore 1950} 142.
`‘33 Fernand Brande], I.r.rjtm' dc? !'éciz::r:gr.
`(.‘it-flisatian naattirielfe, émnornir rt capt'tat't'.m:.w,
`.\'I'er—.\’I’me siérie [1 (Paris
`1979} 81-2.
`95 Douglass C. =.\lorth, Iiutitutiomj, iru'£itu.'iana£ change aim’ eranwmis ;.:e'ig"t}.=marire (Cambridge 1990} 3.
`
`16
`
`16
`
`

`
`state. The institutional framework of markets generally consists of a combination of
`
`formal and informal institutions.
`
`The theory of institutional economics argues that institutional innovation takes
`
`place because economic. actors always search for ways to reduce transaction costs. Put
`
`another way, economic actors always search for ways to obtain benefits from eco-
`
`nomic interaction al the lowest transaction costs possible.“ ./\cemoglu,‘]ohnson and
`
`Robinson divide transactions costs into three categories: ‘lj those that increased the
`
`mobility of capital; 2) those that lowered information costs; and
`
`those that spread
`
`risk.’9*" These three categories will be addressed in this study. I will show how the de-
`
`velopment of a sophisticated enforcement mechanism ensured traders that their trans-
`
`actions would be consummated by the market. Because traders had a high level of
`
`certainty that their trades would be completed, they were more inclined towards trad-
`
`ing, which increased the mobility of capital. The market also lowered information
`
`costs. The use of intermediaries and particularly the creation of trading clubs, whose
`
`participants could easily monitor each other’s behavior, meant that less effort was
`
`needed to check a possible counte1party’s creditworthiness. Furthermore, as a result of
`
`the high trading activity, the share price was constantly updated to the beliefs of the
`
`trading populations.‘-’‘‘ This reduced the need for investors with long-term investment
`
`horizons to find price-relevant information; they could rely on the prices quoted on
`
`the exchange. Lastly, the range of derivative instruments available to the traders by
`
`the second half of the seventeenth century allowed them to mitigate the risk of their
`
`investment portfolios.
`
`Scope and struc.-fure
`
`The scope of this book is limited to the seventeenth-century Amsterdam market for
`
`\-’(_)('.' shares. The focus on the seventeenth century flows, in the first place, from the
`
`fact that it is widely known, mainly from De la Vega’s work, that Amsterdam boasted
`
`3' Sheilagh Ogilt-"ie, “‘\'\-'hatever is, is right"? Economic institutions in pre-industrial Europe’, Economic
`liixtogr :':::,!im! 50 (2007) 649-684, there 656.
`‘-*7‘ North, Institiitioos‘, I25. Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson, ‘Institutions as a
`fundamental cause oflong-run growth", in: Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf (eds), Handbook of
`rcrmoriiio g'ro£t:f/i [Amsterdam 2005) 385-472.
`9“ According to Ross Levine, markets with high trading activity provide an incentive for traders to
`gather price-relevant information: ‘Intuitively, with larger and more liquid markets, it is easier for an
`agent who has acquired information to disguise this private information and make money by trading in
`the market.’ As a result, prices on liquid markets reveal relatively more information about the assets
`that are being traded. Ross Levine, ‘Finance and growth: theory and c\-'ide11ce.°, in: Philippe Aghion and
`Steven N. Durlauf(eds.), Ifooribuofir q,"ero:ioo:ir,:,rroLo!!i {Amsterdam 2005) 865-934, [here 872.
`
`17
`
`17
`
`

`
`a highly sophisticated securities market by the end of the seventeenth century, but the
`
`path of development towards becoming the first modern securities market has re-
`
`mained obscure. Secondly, a study on the seventeenth-century Amsterdam securities
`
`market provides new material for future research on the transfer of financial know-
`
`how from Amsterdam to London in the late seventeenth century. The London securi-
`
`ties market started developing quickly from around 1688 onwards - shortly after the
`
`invasion and subsequent accession to the English throne of Dutch stadholder ‘William
`
`III. Although Nlurphy has recently argued that the London market developed largely
`
`by itself, the timing of the stock market boom in London still suggests that the Dutch
`
`experience must have had some influence on the developments in England.” This
`
`book on the securities market in Amsterdam will aid new researchers in identifying to
`
`what extent the London financial markets profited from Dutch financial experience.
`
`It
`
`is important to note that Amsterdam was not the only city in the seven-
`
`teenth-century Dutch Republic where a secondary market for company equity ex-
`
`isted. The organizational structure of the \-*'O(:, with six serni—independent chambers,
`
`resulted in the emergence of six separate markets. However, due to the smaller capital
`
`stock of" the Middelburg, linkhuizen, Hoorn, Delft and Rotterdam chambers, these
`
`peripheral markets experienced different development paths. Shares in these cham-
`
`bers were, of course, occasionally transferred, but what this study tries to unravel is
`
`how the transition took place from a market where company shares were occasionally
`
`transferred to a thriving securities market that provided its participants a range of fi-
`
`nancial services. This happened only in Amsterdam.” I will also pay some attention to
`
`Middelburg, however. The Middelburg chamber of the \-’()C had the second-largest
`
`capital stock and consequently, the development of the Middelburg market came clos-
`
`est to that of Amsterdam. As I will show in chapter 5, traders used the liquidity of the
`
`Middelburg market for arbitrage* purposes; they tried to be the first to use informa-
`
`tion avaiiable on the Amsterdam market for transactions on the Middelhurg market
`
`and vice versa.‘-"-° Finally, shares in the Dutch ‘Vest India Company (WICI, founded
`
`1623) were also traded on the secondary market. However, investors generally kept
`
`away from these shares. The disproportionately large government interference in the
`
`3'7 .\-'Iu1'phy, 7710 origins qf'Errgl'is':’t_/inrrrrriaf nraralrctv, 5.
`2” The development ofthe markets in equity of the smallest chambers stalled soon after the subscription
`of I602. See chapter 52. section Di\-‘crgient developments: Amsterdam and peripheral markets on page
`68 fl".
`
`9-“ Cf. page 169 ll‘.
`
`18
`
`18
`
`

`
`wit: made investors afraid that the company management would behave too opportu-
`
`nistically. Moreover, investors were well aware that the wI('.' was a financial disaster. I
`
`will therefore focus on the trade in \-'OC shares only.
`
`My analysis of the development of the secondary market for \--'(.)C shares into
`
`the first modern securities market is structured in two parts. Part I treats the seven-
`
`teenth—centtrry history of the market in general. Part It explores in more detail how the
`
`market was organized.
`
`Part I starts, in chapter 1, with a chronological overview of the key develop-
`
`ments that shaped the market during the seventeenth century. Subsequently, chapter
`
`2 analyzes long-term developments, such as the increase in trading activity on the
`
`market, the number of active traders, the dividend policy of the \-"DC and the diverg-
`
`ing development of the Amsterdam market in comparison with the peripheral share
`
`markets in the Dutch Republic. The findings of part I show that after the important
`
`first decade of the century in which the market emerged, the Amsterdam market for
`
`\-'00 shares entered into a second stage of development in the period 1630-50; this
`
`stage brought about the transition into a modern securities market. The two principal
`
`developments during this period were a staggering increase in trading activity and the
`
`appearance of new groups of traders on the market.
`
`Part 11 goes deeper into the developments that made the organization of risky
`
`financial transactions possible in a market that grew in size and became increasingly
`
`anonymous and hence answers the question how the market for VOC shares could
`
`develop into a modern securities market. Chapter 3 discusses the formal and informal
`
`institutions that guaranteed that traders lived up to their agreements. My argument is
`
`that
`
`the traders built a private enforcement mechanism on top of a formal legal
`
`framework. The private enforcement mechanism was needed because large parts of
`
`the forward trade were unenforceable by law. Because of the existence of a clear legal
`
`framework, which took shape through official regulations and court judgments in the
`
`first three decades of the seventeenth century, traders knew exactly whicli transactions
`
`were unenforceable by law. This awareness was key to the good functioning of the
`
`market: the traders recogiized the risks of the forward trade and adjusted their deal-
`
`ings accordingly.
`
`In chapter 4-, I discuss how traders could use the market to manage and con-
`
`trol their financial risks - this being the princip

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket