throbber

`
`101101
`
`
`
`IBG LLC ET AL. - EXHIBIT 1015 PART 2IBG LLC ET AL. - EXHIBIT 1015 PART 2
`
`101
`
`IBG LLC ET AL. - EXHIBIT 1015 PART 2
`
`

`

`3 CONTRACT ENFORCEMENT
`
`Introduction
`
`An active market will develop only if traders can be sure that their trades will be exe-
`
`cuted by the market.' A trader will be hesitant to enter into a transaction if his coun-
`
`terparty can renege on his obligations without suffering adverse effects. So, for the
`
`development of the secondary market for \-’O(; shares, some kind of mechanism for
`
`contract enforcement had to be in effect. Fortunately, the Low Countries already had
`
`a long history of commercial contracting when share trading started in 1602, so mer-
`
`chants and legal institutions were experienced in enforcing commercial transactions?
`
`Moreover, the legal system acknowledged its important role in the development of
`
`trade. In Antwerp, the comme.rcial metropolis of the sixteenth-century, the legal insti-
`
`tutions interacted with the merchant community and promoted the merchants’ inter-
`
`ests.3
`
`Share trading did thus not emerge in a legal void. On the contrary, the legal
`
`principles that applied to the transactions on the share market were already in exis-
`
`tence and hence the share transactions fitted into existing categories of commercial
`
`law. The laws that applied to the transfer of title of a share, for example, were the
`
`same as those that applied to the transfer of ownership of real estate - both were con-
`
`sidered immovable goods under Dutch law." However, not everything was clear from
`
`the start, as the large number of conflicts between share traders that ended up in
`
`lengthy court cases in the period before 1630 shows. For period 1510-30, I have found
`
`thirty lawsuits dealing with share-trade-related court cases in the archives of the Court
`
`of Holland in The Hague.-3 This provincial court pronounced judgment in about 150
`
`' O'Hara, ‘Optimal microstruetures’, 831-2.
`‘~’ Sec, e.g., Herman van der Wee, T728 growth of tin.’ xlrtttt-‘sip rnnrltrt and tits’ E.=n'opean rconorry ofmn'£eentlt—
`.ri.rt.*:.-3:101 cerztttries) I] [The Hague I963}. Oscar Celderblom, Cr.-ty?out3'ng ttinfence and npfiortwtism. The organiza-
`tion rgfilong-(J'i.t'tr.=rt(e trade in Bmgges, ;'lnttt.'er,f) rum’ Arn.n‘e:'dam_. I250—}6'5I’) (manuscript 2009).
`3 Date de Ruysscher, Hmtdel m rrcltt in die Anraerptr: rmttrltnrtlr (I 535-17 1'3), Llnpnolishccl PhD thesis [K.U.
`Lcuven 2009).
`1 See footttote 28 on page 98.
`Helueen Kole generously shared the notes she made for Oscar Gelderblom in the Court of Holland
`archives with me. She used a sample of court cases over the period 1585-1630 in which litigants ap-
`peared whose last names started with B, l\'I or P. In addition to her sample, I used the name index (N.-\,
`Court of Holland, inv. nr.
`lU?'7] to look up all cases whose litigants are known to also have been share
`traders. There are no share-trade-related court cases available prior to 1610; which can be explained by
`the facts that it took several years before the court p1'o11ounecd judgment, that there were relatively few
`trades in the first years after 1602 and that share traders started using more advanced financial tech-
`niques {forward trading, short selling} only from I607 onwards.
`
`102
`
`102
`
`

`

`cases per year, which means that one percent of the cases concerned share transac-
`
`tions.
`
`After 1640, however, the ratio decreased to about one in every five-hundred
`
`lawsuits.“ I will show in the first section of this chapter that in the earliest decades of
`
`the development of the secondary market for V00 shares, traders started litigation to
`
`test the bounds of the existing legal concepts. These litigants were convinced that
`
`there existed some space to maneuver within the rule of law. They were willing to
`
`enter into costly litigation - lawsuits before the appeal courts of Holland became espe-
`
`cially costly if‘ litigants kept adducing new evidence and appealing judgmentsi - that
`
`took up a great amount of effort; lawsuits that were ultimately brought before the
`
`Court of Holland could take anywhere between three-and-a-half‘ and twelve years.3
`
`From around 1640 onwards, however, traders no longer brought their share-
`
`trade-related conflicts before the higher courts. By then, the Court of Holland had
`
`pronounced judgment on all legal concepts that applied to the share trade. Hence-
`
`forth, share traders could predict how the courts would decide in share-trade-related
`
`conflicts. Traders were no doubt abreast of the jurisprudence concerning the share
`
`trade and they regarded the Court of‘ Holland as the authoritative institution regard-
`
`ing new interpretations of the law; they explicitly referred to earlier judgments of the
`
`" There are twenty so-called extended sentences of lawsuits dealing with sliare-trade—related conflicts
`available for the period 1640-] T00. I have used the name index {-N.»-X, Court of Holland, inv. nr. 1078) to
`look up all cases fin‘ which I knew that the litigants (or their close relatives) trad ed shares. Additionally, I
`have checked all lawsuits listing names of Portuguese Jews.
`7 In the case between the directors olltlte VOC: and Abraham de Ligne c.s., for example, the costslb1'tl1e
`repo11 made by o11e of the Councilors of the High Council already amounted to f 126; each party l1ad to
`pay half. This sum does not include the costs of lower courts, the process sen-'cr, the solicitors’ fee and
`taxes. ;\‘;\, High Council, it]\'. or. 64-2, 7 December H52]. These reports usually constituted hall‘o[‘thc
`cottrt’s total costs; a bill in the Cardoso fantily’s estate shows that the report constituted about 50 per-
`cent of the court’s costs: f36 on a total ol‘f59.2ll. Rachel Cardoso had to pay half of this amount
`{f28.=l—0), to which a total off] 2.90 taxes were added: bill Parnassim of the Jewish community of Am-
`sterdam :..-_r. Rachel Cardoso, 2 Novemlner 1712, estate David Abraham Cardoso, SA.-\, PIG, inv. nr. 654-.
`The reports of the Court of Holland's .-snmrrtistrtrtssert (e.g. NA, Cottrt of Holland, int-'. nr. 13.35, for the
`year I672] sometimes also include the hill of the court’s process server. He charged f3.7'5 for every
`summons. The clerk ofthe court’s oflice chargedf6.20 per document. The bill could become steep ifa
`lawsuit inx-‘olvcd several litigants who all had to be sewed summons individttally.
`“ The main factor ofinliuence on the variation in duration was the amount of time litigants let go by
`before they submitted a request for appeal. The Court of Holland of course employed a maximum term
`to request an appeal, but the court could make exceptions for special cases. l\-foreovcr. a lower court’s
`judgment could be suspended for the duration ofthe appeal trttanderirtrnt in ms z.-‘rm rtppetj only ifthe appeal
`had been requested within a short period: M.-Ch. le Bailly, Hr_JfL'an Holland, zrrfitrtd an I-'l"r.t't-Frie5t'artd.' rt’:
`altotp/irt’l'_f,t'neri rrm fret fjrorzderert
`in rt't-‘in’: zatlten near her‘ Ht_Jft.-'13:: Iloltlatid, Zsslarral an |'rfr'=e*.t't-if7r*.=}?5l'rrrta' zonal in eer.t'.-fie
`t'n5:‘a:ttie edit in [anger brraegli EHil\-'ersun1 2008} 26. Le Bailly does not mention the maximum periods before
`lodging an appeal.
`
`92
`
`103
`
`103
`
`

`

`Court of Holland ifa new conflict arose.” The courts’ jurisprudence can thus be re-
`
`garded as securities law.
`
`The legal certainty that emanated from the judgments of the Court of Holland
`
`reduced investors’ hesitancy - smaller merchants and, most prominently, Portuguese
`
`_]ews - to participate in the share trade. As a result of the establishment of a clear legal
`
`framework, the market grew considerably in size.'” Focusing on transaction costs can
`
`help to understand how legal certainty can persuade people to invest: the formation of
`
`a clear legal framework reduced the costs of protecting contractors’ rights and also of
`
`costly enforcement of agreements by a third party, i.e. the court.‘ '
`
`However, the legal certainty applied only to part of the market: shareholders
`
`were allowed to trade only shares they legally owned on the spot and forward markets.
`
`The possibilities for growth were thus limited by the size ofthe \-‘DC capital stock -- the
`
`amount of legal shares available on the market. The sources clearly show that a num-
`
`ber of traders performed far more transactions than their shareholdings would legally
`
`allow. Jacob Athias and Manuel Levy Duarte, for example, had monthly share turn-
`
`overs on the forward market during the period 1683-4 of between 200,000 and
`
`f2,000,000.'9 At the same time, however, there were only very few mutations regis-
`
`tered on their account in the capital book ofthe Amsterdam chamber and their nomi-
`
`nal position never exceeded _f3,000. In June 1684, they liquidated their position.”
`
`Their forward trades generally netted out, so they did not take large short positions in
`
`the VOC, but their official ownership of shares was nevertheless insufficient to legally
`
`justify their forward sales. These were, in other words, short sales and would not be
`
`enforced by the courts.” I will argue in the second section that the participants of the
`
`forward market were aware of this. They therefore established a private enforcement
`
`mechanism that replaced the rule of law. This mechanism, which was in force in the
`
`‘-' Diego d‘Aguirre, Duarte Rodrigues Mendcs. Antonio do Porto and lsaack Comes Sil\-‘era, for exam-
`ple, referred to ajudgment of the Clourl ufHulland ill a claim they submitted to the Court ofAlde1'rner1
`{I8 September 1672}: S.-\.-\, Notaries, inv. nr. il-075, pp. 186-9.
`'“ Cf. Chapter 2; particularly Figure 2.1 (p. ?6} and Figure 2.2 (p. 7?}.
`” North, In.t'h}‘rt£iem', 27.
`'9 S.-\.-\, PIG, inv. nrs. 687-8. The values given are market values.
`'5‘ Interestingly, their nominal position in the \'OC.' lluetuatecl I1-etweenf9,000 andf27,000 in the years
`H380 and l68i; NA, \"('J(.', inv. nr. 707?, f0. 23.’), 383. Unfo1'tun;ttely, their finwarcl trading activity dur-
`ing these years is unknown.
`Isaac le Maire on page 24- ll". The ban
`"' For the ban on short selling, see chapter 1, section I609-l0
`of [610 was reissued in 1623, 162-1», 1630, i636 and 1677. Placard 3_]u11e 1623: Can, (}:r;0!;Jr’arae£-bore/r
`I, 555—‘:l. Placard 20 May 1624: Ibidem, 665-T. Plaeard l October 1630: lbidcm, 667, Plaeard 27 May
`1636: Ibitiem, 667. Placard I6 September I677: Catt, (£t'oot,{:l'ame*£—lJue::k III, l30?.
`
`104
`
`104
`
`

`

`trading clubs”, was based on the traders’ reputations and the condition that each par-
`
`ticipant benefited from suborclirlating to it.
`
`The line of argument is thus as follows: courtjudgments in the first decades of
`
`the seventeenth century created a level of legal certainty that induced the entry to the
`
`market of new groups of traders. The subsequent growth could no longer fit within the
`
`legally approved boundaries of the market and created the need for a sub-market
`
`where a private enforcement mechanism was in force and where access restrictions
`
`made sure that only trustworthy traders could participate.
`
`The two parts of this chapter build on two different fields of historiography.
`
`The first deals with the development of commercial law in Northwestern Europe and
`
`third—party enforcement of trade-related conflicts. In the province of Holland, the law
`
`consisted ofa combination of Roman law and customary law, compiled by the famous
`
`jurist Hugo de Groot (Grotius).“5 Gcldcrblom has argued that this was not a static law.
`
`The Hoflandscfte Cons'itt’£atié}z, a seventeenth-century collection of legal advices compiled
`
`by jurists working for the provincial Court of Holland show that this court based its
`
`judgments ‘on a combination of Roman law, local and foreign customs, Habshurg
`
`ordinances, and Italian and Spanish mercantile law’.” It is therefore interesting to
`
`study the sentences of the Court of Holland in detail - in pronouncingjudgments on
`
`share-trade-related court cases this court’s judges drafted the world’s first securities
`
`law. Banner has traced the origins of Anglo-American securities regulation from the
`
`eighteenth century onwards. He analyzed attitudes towards the trade in securities and
`
`studied how these influenced the regulation of the trade. Banner found that although
`
`the societies and the authorities in England and the United States were often ill-
`
`disposed towards the trade in financial securities, leading to bans on the trade of spe-
`
`cific derivatives, the courts kept enforcing the contracts. They based their judgments
`
`on general legal concepts rather than on the attitudes of the general public, thus giving
`
`legal protection to the trade. '“
`
`The second focuses on private enforcement mechanisms. The most influential
`
`works on this topic have focused on international trade. The difficulty of monitoring
`
`business partners abroad required a high level of commitment by all partners in-
`
`'7‘ See, For a general introduction on trading clubs, chapter 1, section 16605 -- ’l':'atlin_t>; clubs on page 45
`[ll
`
`"5 R.C. van Caenegem, G£.tcIriedkrrnd{ge Errfeiding .Er;H'rt’£,t1.='itIrz(rh't’r:’tf (Ghent l98l_] 5 l.
`'7 Gcldcrblom, Chnflnntingtriolenrr mm’ omnrmnirm, 356.
`'” Banner, Arrgt'a—/lm:=rfrr::: sm:rft.=}>.s' rrgufatiurr.
`
`94»
`
`105
`
`105
`
`

`

`volvecl. Greif has shown for the eleventh—century trade between North Africa and Italy
`
`that traders organized themselves in coalitions. This coalition-forming created a situa-
`
`tion in which even traders who did not know each other personally were willing to
`
`trade with one another. The system worked so well because all participants benefited
`
`from it.” The share market cannot be seen as an example of international trade,
`
`though. While foreign traders occasionally participated, the majority of the traders
`
`came from Amsterdam. But the trading community did not consist ofa homogeneous
`
`grottp of traders either - particularly after the Sephardic community of Amsterdam
`
`started participating in the market from the 1640s onwards. Hence the forward mar-
`
`ket was characterized by a large heterogeneous group of traders who pttt very large
`
`amounts of money at stake. How did they make sure that all members of the trading
`
`community lived up to their agreements?
`
`Court cases form the most important source for this chapter’s analysis. A short
`
`review of the procedure of civil litigation in the Dutch Republic is therefore indispen-
`
`sable. Conflicts concerning share transactions on the Amsterdam market would usu-
`
`ally lirst come up before the local court of Amsterdam. The archives of this court have
`
`been lost, however, so my argument is based on the extended sentences that are avail-
`
`able in the archives of the Court of Holland and - to a lesser extent - the High Coun-
`
`cil. The Court of Holland was the court of appeal for cases that had come up before
`
`one of the local courts in Holland. After this court had pronounced judgment, litigants
`
`could appeal to the High Council, but this court was neither more authoritative, nor
`
`more inlluential; the only di{i'ercnee was that the High Council also had jurisdiction
`
`over the province of Zeelandfz"
`
`The near total loss of the archives ofthe local court ofAmsterdam is a pity, but
`
`these sources are not indispensable for my argument, since my main interest concerns
`
`the development of jurisprudence on share trade. It is to be expected that the local
`
`court ofAmsterdam could very well deal with most of the share-trade-related conflicts.
`
`There are indications that share traders went to the Amsterdam court to exact pay-
`
`ment or delivery ofa share from their eounterparties9‘, but these were probably not
`
`"-' Avner Gr-:'if'_. ‘Reputation and coalitions in nieclieval trade: F.vidence on the Maghribi traders‘, 77:9
`jotttrtal oferonontic a"tt'.t'£o{‘,u 4-9 H989} 857-882.
`1"‘ ;\-'l.—Cl1. le Bailly and Chr. i\-'I.O. \-*'erhas, Huge Reed’ van Hoflartd. Zeefartrf on l1"e?s!—I'i‘t'e*n’ctrtrf (1582—l'79.'3J.'
`dc? tmfitym am: last pt'0r'e’(t’er.€H in (fairly zaker: mar dr? Ifqsgr Read zrtumt in mr,s'te irtstaittie air in ltogrr be°.=‘oe,b {Hilve 1'-
`sum 2006) 7.
`21 This is based on the amirtttrttirs in the protocols of Anisterdanfs notarics. An ierirttmtie, or notarial
`summons, was usually the first step in legal action. The protocols of 1672 and 1688, two years with
`
`106
`
`"-DLn
`
`106
`
`

`

`the most interesting cases. However, if one of the parties was convinced that there
`
`were several possible interpretations of a lawsuit, he would appeal the judgment of the
`
`lower c.ourt to the Court of Holland. Hence, those cases are particularly important for
`
`a reconstruction of the development of a legal framework.
`
`The procedure of litigation before the Court of Holland was as follows. The
`
`plaintiff first submitted a petition to the court, listing a short summary of the case and
`
`his principal arguments. The court then, provided that it had approved the petition,
`
`entered the case onto the scroll (ml), the list of cases to be dealt with by the court.
`
`Thereafter, the plaintiff could summon the defendant to appear in court. The plain-
`
`tiffs solicitor then submitted his claim to the court, to which the defendant could re-
`
`spond within two weeks’ time. Thereafter, both parties could submit a rejoinder,
`
`which could take another four weeks in total. Both parties had now set forth their po-
`
`sitions, but the court could ask the parties to submit more information or to prove a
`
`certain argument.
`
`Naturally, both the plaintiff and the defendant adduced evidence, for example
`
`attestations before a notary, questionings of witnesses and other forms of written evi-
`
`dence such as brokers’ records.” Conflicting parties often asked other merchants or
`
`brokers - people, in sum, who were demonstrably well informed about the share trade
`
`- to attest before a notary public.” They attested, for instance, the customary way of
`
`trading shares or the share price at a certain date. They could also give a report as a
`
`witness.'3’* Case files that contain all written evidence are available for some lawsuits.‘-’5
`
`'t'Vhcn the court had collected all
`
`the necessary information, it pronounced
`
`judgment. A report of the court procedure was included in the collection of extended
`
`sentences of the Court of Holland. This collection, as well as the collection of ex-
`
`tended sentences of the High Council, contains reports of all cases in which the judges
`
`took some sort of action. These collections thus also contain lawsuits in which, for in»
`
`stance, the judges referred the litigants to mediators. This means that my sources are
`
`large price fluctuations and consequently many conflicts between share traders, contain high numbers
`of i;t.ti'ni1at‘ie*.r. It is very well possible that these conflicts were also brought before the local court. Only
`one conflict stemming from a transaction in 1672 and one from a transaction in 1688 reached the
`Court of Holland, ltowever.
`33 See for the types of cviclcnce accepted by the courts: Gelderblom, Corfl'or:£iag:.=inlear:e. 2?2—3.
`33‘ Cf. Van Mceteren, Op hoop mm akkoorra’, 172-3. According to \-"an l\-'Ieeteren_. fiir an attestation to be
`credible, it had to be attested to a notaiy public as soon after the event had happened as possible: Van
`Meetcren, Op itaap trait akkaoin’, I8] .
`3" E.g. N.-\, Case files, lI]\-'. nr. ll'l‘39.
`25 N.-\, Case files. l\Eorinally, litigants received the contents of the case file back when the court proce-
`dure was Iinished. However, some litigants did not collect the case files.
`
`96
`
`107
`
`107
`
`

`

`not biased by the selection procedure of the clerk of the court. It is true, however, that
`
`my method of research excludes those cases that reached amicable settlement before
`
`the courts’ mediators. Again, this is not problematic: I have checked the reports of
`
`mediators in the years after 16?? when the price crash led to a high number of con-
`
`flicts - but the share-trade-related cases in these reports deal with relatively minor
`
`issues. The litigants whom the lower courts had ruled against simply appealed to the
`
`Court of Holland to postpone the execution of the lower court’s judgment. Subse-
`
`quently, the Court of Holland realized that it was no use to start a full court procedure
`
`again and referred the litigants to mediation?“ So, to conclude, the extended sen-
`
`tences of the provincial courts of Holland are the right sources to use for an analysis of
`
`the development ofjurisprudence on share-trade-related issues.
`
`‘Nee legaffiamework
`
`Conflicts about share transactions could involve three legal concepts: ownership and
`
`the transfer of ownership, endorsement* and the terms of settlement of a transaction.
`
`The courts of the province of Holland refined jurisprudence on these concepts by
`
`judging on a number of court cases. All three legal concepts will subsequently be ad-
`
`dressed in the lbllowing subsections.
`
`O\\’NERSHlP AND 'I'l{+\_\'Sl“I’.R OF O\-\'N[’.RSHlP
`
`Clear rules for share ownership and the transfer of share ownership were crucial for
`
`the development of the secondary market. Under Roman-Dutch law, the general rule
`
`for transfer of title was that ownership passed on the basis of delivery. Since \-"OC
`
`shares were not payable to the bearer, however, they could not be physically deliv-
`
`ered, so a special rule for the conveyance of ownership was needed. The directors of
`
`the \-'OC were aware of this and therefore they included a rule that regulated how in-
`
`vestors could ascertain and convey share ownership in the subscription book of 1602.
`
`Shareholders owned those shares registered under their account in the capital books
`
`that were kept by the company bookkeeper. Title to a share could be transferred by
`
`means of oflicial registration.“ This procedure was similar to the procedure for trans-
`
`‘-"5 N.-\, Court of Holland, inv. nrs. I552, I559.
`97 Tlie lirst page of the Amsterdaln Chamber's subscription book stated this rule. Transcript of this page
`{followed by the entire book): Van Dillcn, A(Indra£'!:nudrr.sregi.s'ter, I05-6. See also chapter 1 section I602 -
`The subscription on page 17 ll‘.
`
`108
`
`108
`
`

`

`ferring unmovable goods such as real estate. Hence, the law also classified shares as
`
`unrnovable goods?“
`
`Van Balck as. Rotgans (1622) marlcs an important step in clarifying the rules
`
`{or ownership ofa share. This case made clear that a shareholder could be certain that
`
`the shares listed on his account in the capital book of the VOC were his full property
`
`and that previous holders ofthe ownership ofthe share could not lay claims on it. The
`
`judges thus confirmed the legal force ofthe capital books. The plaintiifin this lawsuit,
`
`Allert van Balck, believed that he had right of vindication on the share he had trans-
`
`ferred tojan Hendricksz. Rotgans. Right of vindication means that the transferor of a
`
`good could reclaim ownership if the good had not been fully paid for or if he could
`
`prove that the purchaser had practiced fraud at the time of the transaction - for ex-
`
`ample hy hiding his impending insolvency or fleeing from town without paying?" Van
`
`Balck had transferred a share, but he never received full payment and therefore
`
`claimed the ownership of the share.
`
`Van Balck had sold this particular share to Hans Bouwer on April 5, 1610.
`
`Bouwer, for his part, sold a similar share to Rotgans on the next day. Rotgans ap-
`
`proached Van Balck on the exchange, saying that he. wanted to receive his share, but
`
`Van Balck replied that he did not know Rotgans and that he had traded with Bouwer.
`
`Rotgans then explained the situation and told Van Balck that he should transfer the
`
`share to him; he would pay himfl,000 and Bouwer would see to the payment of the
`
`remaining sum. Van Balck agreed to transfer the share, but he never received full
`
`payment: Bouwer left Amsterdam in the following days to flee from his creditors. Van
`
`Balck went to court, where he requested seizure of the share, but the Court of Alder-
`
`men refused to adjudicate this; the judges reasoned that Van Balck no longer had title
`
`to the share after he had transferred it to Rotgans. Van Balck argued that he still had
`
`the right of mortgage of the share, because he had never received full payment. In his
`
`view, he still had a claim on Bouwer’s share and hence on Rotgans' payment to Bon-
`
`‘-’” Tlle Cfrinsrtttrrtierr, a liunous compilation ol'eaI‘ly-modern Utttcli jl.ll‘iS[)I‘l1d{:‘l1£'C.. confirms ll1at the courts
`treated shares as immo\~ables in the winding up ol‘ estates: C.‘uns'm‘tatim, adzysm an adz.-ertismrie*m’er:_. ge'_:;ez;er.=
`emrfe gesc/trewr: by a.wm’ig}'rt't=..r: t:'gf]ét'§irke .=m':ts'—geEa°rde:: in Holtaridt I (Rotterdam 1645] T7, 139-40. In Fniglancl,
`it had been unclear after the foundation ofthe lirstjoint-stock companies whether common law treated
`shares as real or personal property-'. This had implications for the translerability of shares. Subsequent
`incorporation acts added a clause that declared shares to be personal property: Harris, I:ia‘tt.s'm'ati.zing
`Engt’i.t'1i
`t'(It£.',
`ll7-8. In the Dutch Republic, there were no impediments to the transfer of unmovable
`goods other than the obligation to oflicially register a transfer.
`2*’ De G root, .’r.=£eir1t‘r:_gr= Ilzlaritateiiirigeit, 236.
`
`98
`
`109
`
`109
`
`

`

`wer. Van Balck appealed the Aldermen’s decision before two higher courts, but both
`
`the Court of Holland and the High Council also ruled against him.”
`
`The fact that Van Balck and his lawyer appealed the courts’ decisions twice
`
`indicates that this was not a clear-cut case. This lawsuit was not just about the right of
`
`vindication; Bouwer had practiced fraud, so there was little doubt that Van Balck had
`
`right of vindication. However, the courts had to balance Van Balck’s right of vindica-
`
`tion and the rights of Rotgans, who gave the impression that he was a sincere buyer
`
`who had paid for the transfer, against each other. Rotgans was not as sincere as he
`
`had the court believe, in fact, he was in league with Rotgans, but Van Balck did not
`
`succeed in convincing the court of Rotgans’ insincerity.3' In the end, the courts fa-
`
`vored the interests of the buyer who had purportedly done nothing wrong.
`
`This judgment had far-reaching consequences; with it, the courts safeguarded
`
`the interests of commerce. Share trading could have been severely hampered had Van
`
`Balck won this lawsuit, because in that case a buyer of a share would always have to
`
`fear that there was still a claim on the share he had bought, which would give. the
`
`seller the right to claim it back.” This particular lawsuit, in other words, took away
`
`legal doubts that could have restrained investors from buying shares on the secondary
`
`market for \--'0(: shares.
`
`Interestingly, a few years before the High Court pronounced final judgment in
`
`this case, the \-’0(.‘ had also recognized the potential problems of transfers of shares
`
`that had claims attached to them. The VOC: feared that buyers would not only lay a
`
`claim on the seller, but also on the company. It therefore changed the share transfer
`
`regulation. From l6 l6 onwards, the buyer of a share had to sign a statement when the
`
`bookkeeper added the share to his account that indemnified the company against any
`
`future claims. The buyer signed that he had accepted a ‘good’ share - a real share, in
`
`other words, a share that had formed part of the capital stock since 1602
`
`and that he
`
`was satisfied with it.”
`
`3” Allerl van Balck E.-‘J’. Jan Hentlricksz. Rotgans, 22 December I622, N.-\, High Council, inv. 11r. 715.
`The iniirturrtie that p1'eceded the court case has beeit published by \-"an Dillen: Van Dillen, ‘Isaac le
`l\-'Iai:'e', I01 (doc. nr. 45]. Pieter Syinoitsx. van der Schclling ended up in a similar situation after trans-
`ferring shares to Hans Bouwer: Van Dillen, ‘Isaac le i\/Iaire’, I08 (doc. nr. 57}.
`3' Van Dillen, ‘Isaac le ;\-Iairc’, I2].
`39 IJ.L. Carey Miller, "l‘ransfer oi'ownership’, in: Robert Feenstrzt and Reinhard 2u.'.Cimmcrman [eds.),
`Dos riiirtisdt-}taHtfndis'cFw Rerlit. I‘h:'t'.rr!'nitt‘r= (I'M Zfz.Ii't'm:Fit‘.s' for 1.7. um} I3. Jrtitrfzttndert Berlin 1997], 52 1-4-0, there
`.327, 53124.
`33* \v"aI1 Dam, Bess/twinge l.-\, I4-1-5.
`
`110
`
`110
`
`

`

`By extension, the same legal principle that the court applied in Van Balck vs.
`
`Rotgans was in force in the forward trade. In a series ofjudgments, the courts ruled
`
`that forward buyers could also expect the underlying asset of their forward contract to
`
`be a real share. There was no need to explicitly state in the contract that the share had
`
`to be free of any claims; the judges held the opinion that that was a matter of course.
`
`The Court of Holland thus clarified the procedure of transfer of ownership in a for-
`
`ward transaction.
`
`The lawsuits that dealt with these matters were to a large extent similar to Van
`
`Balck vs. Rotgans, although they look much more complicated at first sight. These
`
`court cases all started with Pieter Overlander who found out that the share he had
`
`received in settling a forward contract was fraudulent. The seller had transferred a
`
`non-existent share to his account, which the company‘ bookkeeper had knowingly exe-
`
`cuted. The complication of this case lies in the fact that many more traders were in-
`
`volved in this transaction; the transfer of a share to Overlander had settled the con-
`
`tracts of a chain of forward traders. The following description of the lawsuit shows
`
`that these chains oftraders could prove problematic if conflicts arose between one pair
`
`of traders within the chain.
`
`Pieter Overlander had bought a forward with af3,000 \-‘DC share as underly-
`
`ing asset from Abraham Abelijn on 13 Nlarch 1609, but the share was eventually
`
`transferred to him by Hans Bouwer. Abelijn had a similar transaction (a forward with
`
`the same nominal value and settlement date) with Dirck Semeij, who for his part had
`
`bought a similar forward from Maerten de Mcijere. When the contract was due for
`
`delivery, Semeij asked De Meijere to transfer the share directly to Abelijn. De Mei-
`
`jere, however, was to receive a share from Jacques van de Geer and Hans Pellicorne
`
`and therefore he asked Abelijn if he would be satisfied if they delivered the share to
`
`him. Abelijn referred the question to Overlander. But Overlander had just heard a
`
`rumor that Van de Geer and Pellicorne were on the verge of going bankrupt, so he
`
`refused to accept this deal, unless De 1\/Ieijere would explicitly indemnify him against
`
`any trouble. De Meijere then proposed to let Hans Bouwer, who also owed a share to
`
`him, deliver the share instead. Overlander accepted this deal and Abelijn also trusted
`
`that
`
`this transfer would successfully settle all
`
`the abovementioned transactions: he
`
`traded with Bouwer on a daily basis. Overlander had the share transferred to Frans
`
`van Cruijsbergen, his brother-in-law, and each pair of traders in the chain came to-
`
`gether once more to tear up the contracts and pay possible price differences.
`
`IOU
`
`111
`
`111
`
`

`

`A little later, however, the transferred share was found to be fraudulent, so
`
`Overlander started litigation. He summoned Abelijn -
`
`the only trader he had a right-
`
`ful claim on - to appear in court and demanded that Abelijn replace the share with a
`
`good one. What makes this lawsuit so interesting is that the Amsterdam Court of A1-
`
`dermen requested Overlander to give evidence under oath that he had been promised
`
`a ‘sincere and sound’ share on contracting this transaction. His claim would be dis-
`
`missed if he did not take the oath, which reveals that the lower court did not acknowl-
`
`edge the legal principle that the buyer of a good can always expect this good to be
`
`delivered according to the conditions in the contract.
`
`Abeli_jn’s lawyer had made this particular point an important part of the de-
`
`fense, arguing that Overlander had requested to be indemnified against any troubles if
`
`Van de Geer and Pellicorne would have transferred the share, but he had not made
`
`any such requests when Abelijn proposed to let Bouwer transfer the share. Overlander
`
`had thus, according to the defense, accepted the share without reservations.
`
`Overlander did not hesitate to make his declaration under oath and the court
`
`consequently sentenced Abelijn to replace the share. Abelijn then summoned his
`
`original counterparty Semeij, and the Aldermen pronounced the same judgment.
`
`Hence, the chain of share transactions became mirrored in a chain of court cases be-
`
`fore the Court of Aldermen. Furthermore, every one of the defendants appealed the
`
`Aldermen’s sentences to the Court of Holland, resulting in another chain of court
`
`cases (this time the other way around: Abelijn at. Overlander, Semeij vs. Abelijn, ete.),
`
`but the appeals were disallowed. The judges of the Court of Holland did not require
`
`the litigants to

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket