throbber
CHAPTER 5
`
`LOST PROFITS DAMAGES
`
`I.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`To promote the patent system’s incentives to innovate, patent law sets the goal of
`calibrating compensatory damages to replicate the market reward that would have been earned
`absent infringement. As Chapter 4 discusses, damages that undercompensate patentees
`according to that standard undermine the patent system’s incentives to innovate. Damages that
`overcompensate patentees can distort competition and decrease innovation.
`
`One way a patentee can innovate is to develop and commercialize the invention itself.
`For a patentee producing a patented product, the piimaiy importance of the patent is often the
`right it confers to exclude competitors from making and selling a competing product
`incorporating the patented technology. Often the most effective way to remedy infringement in
`this context is by awarding the patentee its profits on sales of the patented product that it lost due
`to the infringement.
`
`To accurately replicate the market reward that the patentee would have earned by
`practicing its invention, the lost profits damages calculation must account for competition that
`the patentee’s product would have faced if the infringer had sold a noninfringing alternative that
`did not incorporate the patented technology. Denying a patentee lost profits damages based on
`the availability of any acceptable alternative, as the seminal Pandm't case seems to suggest, can
`undercompensate the patent holder.1 But ignoring competition from alternatives that would have
`occurred in the absence of infringement, and awarding lost profits based on all infringing sales,
`can overcompensate it. Both outcomes can harm innovation and consumers.2
`
`Determining how the market would have rewarded the invention absent infringement can
`be done by assessing consumer preference for the patented technology and the degree of
`substitutability between the patented technology and noninfringing alternatives.3 That
`assessment can identify the number of consumers that would have purchased the patented
`product in the face of competition and the price they would have paid. The analysis and
`economic tools are similar to those used in antitrust cases to reconstruct a market and measure
`
`the effects of a proposed merger. The case law governing lost profits damages has moved toward
`this more economically grounded analysis since the Pandnit case in 1978. However, additional
`
`lPanduit Corp. V. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works, Inc, 5 75 F.2d 1 152, 1156 (6th Cir. 1978) (requiring an
`absence of suitable noninfringing alternatives).
`
`2336 Chapter 4, Section III.
`
`3For a comprehensive discussion applying economic analysis to the calculation ofpatent damages, see
`ROGER D. BLAIR & THOMAS F. COTTER, INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY: ECONOMIC AND LEGAL DIMENSIONS
`
`OF RIGHTS AND REMEDIES 214—228 (2005); Roger D. Blair & Thomas F. Cotter, Rethinking Patent
`Damages, 10 TEX. INTELL. PROP. L]. 1 (2001).
`
`150
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ862
`RX-0870.156
`
`

`

`improvements, including rejection of rigid rules such as the “entire market value rule” and the
`requirement for dual awards of lost profits and reasonable royalty damages, would increase the
`accuracy of damage awards. Such a result would better align patent damages law and competition
`policy, to the benefit of consumers.
`
`H.
`
`NONINFRINGING ALTERNATIVES IN A LOST PROFITS CALCULATION
`
`A.
`
`The Panduit Test
`
`To receive lost profits damages, a patentee must prove that, but for the infringement, it
`would have earned the lost profits it seeks, and that this loss was a foreseeable consequence of
`infringement. Infringing competition can reduce the patentee’s profits in several ways, including
`by diverting sales from the patentee’s product, eroding the patentee’s sales price, and causing the
`patentee to lose sales of related, non-patented products.4 The “Paaduit test” provides a
`commonly—used framework with which patentees can establish entitlement to test profits
`damages.
`It requires the patentee to prove:
`
`(1)
`
`(2)
`(3)
`
`(4)
`
`there was demand for the patented product in the relevant market during
`the period at issue;
`there were no suitable noninfringing alternatives to the patented product;
`the patentee had the manufacturing and marketing capacity to meet the
`demand claimed; and
`the amount of profit it would have made.5
`
`Pandaz‘t appears to create an allaormnothing test: in the absence of noninfringing
`alternatives, and assuming the patentee satisfies the other criteria, the patentee receives lost
`profits on ali the infringer’s sales. When noninfringing alternatives are available, the patentee
`receives no lost profits.6 Later cases, however, have adopted a more flexible approach that
`allows a patentee to recover lost profits on some, but not all, of the infringer’s sales. For
`instance, in State Industries v. Mar-Flo Industries, the court awarded lost profits damages on the
`portion of infringing sales that corresponded to the patentee’s market share.7 The analysis
`
`‘See Rite—Bite Corp. v. Kelly Co, 56 F.3d 1538, 1546 (Fed. Cir. 1995); TWM Mfg. Co. v. Dura Corp,
`789 F.2d 895, 902 (Fed. Cir. 1986) (price erosion).
`
`SPandutl Corp, 575 F.2d at 1156.
`
`61d.
`
`7883» F.2d l573, l578 (Fed. Cir. 1989); see also Micro Motion, Inc. v. Kane Steel Co.. 894 F.2d 1318
`(Fed. Cir. 1990).
`
`15]
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ863
`RX-0870.157
`
`

`

`assumed that the remainder of the infringer’s customers likely would have chosen alternative
`products. The court described this market share calculation as an alternative to the Pandas? test.S
`
`Panelists and commentators have criticized the Panduit test because the “factors [are]
`
`. necessary conditions” for a lost profits award, when in fact “you can have iost
`.
`stated as .
`profits, even if one or more of them aren’t satisfied.”9 One commentator argues that courts have
`at times imposed unrealistic evidentiaiy burdens on patentees to establish the precise extent of
`their lost profits, thereby relegating them to reasonable royalty recoveries that are not designed to
`remedy their losses.10 Panelists proposed an approach for calculating lost profits focused on
`“[i]dentify[ing] the defendant’s next best alternative to infringing” and then determining “the
`market outcome in the ‘but for’ world where it pursued [that] alternative instead of infringing.
`Further development in the case law along these lines, toward an economically grounded
`calculation of lost profits and away from rigid rules like the Panduit test, would increasc the
`accuracy of lost profit damage awards and help fully compensate patentees. Moreover, courts
`should recognize that a lost profits determination is “not an exact science”12 and permit plaintiffs
`to “approximate, if necessary, the amount to which. the patent owner is entitled.”13
`
`”11
`
`in assessing how the market would have rewarded the
`Recommendation.
`invention absent infringement, courts should allow a patentee flexibility in
`creating the “but for” world to address different losses and avoid
`
`8Bic Leisure Prods, Inc. V. Windsurfing lnt’l, Inc, 1 F.3d 1214, 1219 (Fed. Cir. 1993) (allowing “a
`patentee to recover lost profits, despite the presence of acceptable, noninfringing substitutes, because it
`nevertheless can prove with reasonable probability sales it would have made ‘but for’ the infringement”);
`see also Grain Processing Corp. v. American Maize—Prods, 185 F.3d 1341, 1349-50 (Fed. Cir. 1999)
`(recognizing that but for infringement, the defendant would have participated in the market by using an
`available, noninfringing alternative); In re Mahurkar Double Lumen Hemodialysis Catheter Patent Litig,
`831 F. Supp. 1354, 1390 (N .D. 111. 1993) (Easterbrook, J., sitting by designation) (recognizing that absent
`infringement, the patentee may have made additional sales at a higher prices).
`
`9Leonard at 48 (2/ 1 1/09); Comment of John W. Sehlichcr at 53 (5! 15.109) (“efforts to apply [the Pancfuz’t
`test] have largely been unfruitful”).
`
`10l\/Iark A. Lemley, Distingttis/ting Lost Profits from Reasonable Royalties, 51 WM. & MARY L. REV. 655,
`657—61 (2009). The same article argues that courts have inflated reasonable royalty damages in. an
`attempt to compensate patentees for denied lost profit claims. Id. at 661—69. Chapter 6 discusses the
`detrimental effects of inflating reasonabie royalty damages for this reason.
`
`11Comment of Greg Leonard at 78 (3/9/09); Blair & Cotter supra, note 3 at 15; Vincent E. O’Brien,
`Economics and Key Patent Damages Cases. 9 U. BALT. INTELL. PROP. LJ. 1, 6 (2000); see also Levko at
`59 (2/11/09) (noting that the “but for” world should broadly look at market definition).
`
`12King instrument Corp. v. Otari Corp, 767 F.2d 853, 863 (Fed. Cir. 1985).
`
`13Del Mar Avionics, lnc. V. Quinton Instrument Co., 836 F.2d 1320, 1327 (Fed. Cir. 1987).
`
`152
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ864
`RX-0870.158
`
`

`

`undercornpensation. Patentees should not be denied an opportunity to establish
`lost profits through application of rigid rules that do not reflect sound economic
`principles or imposition of evidentiary requirements beyond what is required for
`the court to make a reasonable approximation of the patentee’s loss.
`
`An economically grounded approach to calculating lost profits damages focuses on the
`market for the patentee’s product. It generally requires considering the sales and prices that the
`patentee actually made and comparing them to the sales it would have made in the “but for”
`worid where the infringer sold a noninfringing alternative, if one is available. That comparison
`involves quantifying the number of sales the patentee lost due to infringement and estimating the
`extent of any price erosion.14 This analysis must consider the extent of consumer preferences for
`the patented feature over alternatives, and not simply treat alternatives as failing on either side Of
`a bright line dividing the acceptahie from the unacceptable.
`instead, the analysis recognizes that
`the “degree of substitutahility” between the patented product and the noninfringing substitute
`will affect the extent of the loss caused by infringement, as opposed to competition generally.15
`
`At one end of the spectrum, consumers freely substitute alternatives for the patented
`product. The infringer could have made neariy as many sales by offering the alternative.
`in such
`a case, the patentee lost few sales due to infringement and should receive little lost profits
`damages.16 The patentee’s recovery is limited because its invention contributes relatively iittie
`value over alternatives, and the damages should reflect this fact. At the other end of the
`spectrum, consumers strongly prefer the patented product over alternatives and will pay higher
`
`l4See, e. g, Gregory J. Werden, Luke M. Froeb & Lucian Wayne Beavers, Economic Analysis Lost Profits
`from Parent Inflingernent With and Without Noninfringing Substitutes, 27 AIPLA QJ. 305, 307—08
`(1999); Gregory K. Leonard, Appiying Merger Simuiation Techniques to Estimate Lost Profit Damages
`in InreZZecraa! Property Litigation, in ECONOMIC APPROACHES TO INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY, POLICY,
`LITIGATION, AND MANAGEMENT 112—13 (Gregmy K. Leonard & Lauren J. Stiroh eds, 2005). The
`analysis should also recognize that at lower prices, the patentee may sell more products, which wiil affect
`the amount Ofprofits lost by infringement. Gregory J. Werden, larcian Wayne Beavers & Luke M.
`Frocb, Quentin: Accretion: Mirror Image ofPrice Erosion from Patent Infringement, 81 J‘. PAT. 82;
`TRADEMARK OFF. SOC’Y 479 (1999); see afso Comment OfJOhn W. Schlicher at 54 (5/1/09).
`
`15In re M’anurftar Doubie Lumen Hemociiaiysis Catheter Patent Litig, 831 F. Supp. at 1390
`(“Competition is not an all-or-nothing proposition. There are degrees of substituability.”); Werden et a1,
`supra note 14, at 310 (noting that “[i]n some sense, there are always substitutes for the patented
`product”).
`
`J6See Grain Processing Corp. V. American Maize~Pmds C0,, 893 F. Supp. 1386, 1392 (NI). ind. 1995)
`(Easterhrook, l, sitting by designation), afl’d in part, vacated in part, 108 F.3d 1392 (Fed. Cir. 1997)
`(awarding no lost profits damages due to availability of alternative); but see Jerry A. Hausrnan, Gregory
`K. Leonard & J. Gregory Sidak, Patent Damages and Real Options: How Judicia! Characterization of
`Noninfiinging Alternatives Reduces Incentives to Innovate, 22 BERKELEY TECH. LJ. 825, 852—53 (2007)
`(arguing that “the district court’s conclusion in Grain Processing that no lost profits existed if the
`infringer were assumed to have adopted the noninfringing technoiogy is at odds with standard economic
`theory”).
`
`153
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ865
`RX-0870.159
`
`

`

`prices for it. In the world without infringement, the patentee likely would have made most of the
`infringer’s sales at a higher price, earning a large return on its invention. It should receive
`substantial lost profits damages adequate to compensate for the market reward it would have
`earned absent infringement. In both cases, the remedy reflects the value of the invention,
`providing proper incentives for invention and innovation. Many patented products and their
`alternatives fall between these two extremes, but these also are entitled to lost profits damages
`when proven.17
`
`Economic analysis of the type used in antitrust merger review can help determine where
`alternatives fall along this spectrum, the number of sales lost to the infringing product, and the
`price erosion caused by infringement.18 Measuring the cross-elasticity of demand between an
`infringing product and noninfringing alternatives can determine their “degrees of
`subs"ti.tutability.”19 Economists have explained that “[slimulating damages from patent
`infringement is quite similar to simulating the effects of a merger. Rather than extrapolating
`from the lower-price, pie—merger equilibrium to the higher-price, post—merger equilibrium, one
`extrapolates from the iower~p1ice, with infringement equilibrium to the higherwprice, but~for~
`infringement equilibrium.”20
`
`B.
`
`The Entire Market Value Rule
`
`The law of lost profits damages recognizes that a patented invention may be only one
`component of a complex product. In that case, not all of the infiinger’s profit, or the patentee’s
`lost profits, is necessarily attributable to the patented invention. The case law traditionally
`addresses this issue by “apportioning” the potential damages according to the value the invention,
`such as a mop head, contributes to the product, such as a mop.21 Modern case law applies the
`“entire market value rule” to determine when to award lost profits damages based on the entire
`
`175363 O’Brien, supra note 1 1, at 6. Cf, Lcmley, supra note 10, at 6751-72 (arguing that a patentee’s
`difficulty in proving precise amount of lost profits damages, as opposed to entitlement to them, should
`not disqualify it from receiving them).
`
`18Blair & Cotter, supm note 3, at 15 —1.6 (“modern economic analysis does provide some techniques for
`estimating losses” based on construction ofa market absent infringement); see also Marion B. Stewart,
`Calculating Economic Damages in, Ineliectuai Property Disputes: The Role OfMarkel' Definition, 77 .l.
`PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC’Y 321 (1995).
`
`19Blair & Cotter, supra note 3, at 13—14, 11.34 (explaining relationship of cross—elasticity of demand to lost
`profits).
`
`20VVerdcn et at, supra note 14, at 303—08.
`
`21Seymour V. McCormick, 57 US. 480, 489—91, (1853) (explaining that damages based on an entire
`machine when the patent covers only a component could subject the infringer to duplicative and
`excessive damages); see also Garretson V. Clark, 11 1 US. 120, 121 (1884) {requiring apportionment of
`damages from sales of a mop based on infringement of patent covering improved mop head).
`
`154
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ866
`RX-0870.160
`
`

`

`value of the patented product. The entire market value rule applies when (1) the patented feature
`is “the basis for customer demand”22 of the infringing product and (2) the patented and
`unpatented components together “constitute a functional unit.”23 For instance, in Golden Bloom,
`Inc. 1/. Robert H. Petenson Can, the Federai Circuit allowed lost profits damages based on the
`entire market value of an artificial fireplace where only the gas burner was patented. The court
`upheld a finding that the burner, logs and grate worked together as a fimctional unit and that the
`ember burner was the basis for customer demand.24
`
`The entire market value rule is not needed in an economic assessment of lost profits.
`indeed, it distracts fact-finders from a carefiil reconstruction of a market lacking infringement.
`Courts should reject it. The rule’s focus on whether a feature is the “basis for customer demand,”
`and allowing only a “yes” or “no” answer to that question, prevents courts and juries from giving
`adequate consideration to the “degrees of substitutability” that may exist with respect to
`noninfringing alternatives.25 In doing so, it inhibits an appreciation of the differences among
`consumers and their preferences for different alternatives. The “functional unit” prong of the
`
`
`
`22Stare Indira, Inc, 883 F.2d at 1580. This “basis of customer demand” standard as sometimes applied is
`arguably more lenient than statements of earlier cases requiring that “the entire value of the whole
`machine, as a marketable article, is properly and legally attributable to the patented feature” for damages
`to be based on the whole product. Garretson, 1 11 US. at 121, (quoting Garretson v. Clark, 10 F. Gas. 40,
`44 (C.C.N.Y. 1878). Compare State Indus, Inc, 883 F.2d at 11580 (allowing lost profits damages based
`on entire water heater where invention related to foam insulation) with Marconi. Wireless Tele. Co. v.
`United States, .99 Ct. Cl. 1., 21 (Ct. Cl. 1942). afl’d in part, vacated in part, 320 US. l (l943) (holding
`that patentee can recover damages based on an entire product if patented feature “was of such paramount
`importance that it substantially created the value of the component parts”).
`
`23Rite~Hite Corp, 56 F.3d at 1550 (lost profits damages may be based on the entire market value of a
`product only where “the patented and unpa’tented components were analogous to a single functioning
`unit” and may not be extended to include unpatented items “that have essentially no functional
`relationship to the patented invention and that may have been sold with an infringing device only as a
`matter of convenience or business advantage”).
`
`2"’438 F.3d 1354, l3?1-?2 (Fed. Cir. 2006). Sec 625.90 Tec Air, Inc. v. Denso Mfg. Michigan, Inc., l92
`F.3d 1353, 1361 (Fed. Cir. 1999) (damages based on entire assembly where infringing fans were sold
`with noninfringing radiator and condenser).
`
`25The “basis for consumer demand” standard is not a good proxy for those instances in which no
`alternatives for the patented invention exist such that the patentee would have made all infringing sales.
`The standard has been liberally applied in. some cases, and it fails to focus on the operative economic
`question of noninfringing competition. See Golden Bloom, Inc., 438 F.3d at 1371 (allowing damages
`based on entire artificial, fireplace when only gas burner was patented, without examining noninfringing
`competition in artificial fireplace market); Tee Air, Inc., 192 F.3d at 1361 (damages based on entire
`assembly where infringing fans were sold with noninfringing radiator and condenser because consumer
`demand was based on performance of entire assembly).
`
`155
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ86?
`RX-0870.161
`
`

`

`rule makes the determination of damages hinge on a distinction that is irrelevant to
`reconstruction of a market lacking infringement.26
`
`The all or nothing aspect of the entire market value rule detracts from the ability of patent
`damages to provide compensation to patentees that reflects the value of their inventions, and
`thereby align with competition policy. A more nuanced economic analysis can help identify the
`extent to which infringement causes a patentee to lose profits whether the patent at issue claims
`the entire infringing product or one component of that product. When consumers View a
`patented component as a vaiuable feature of a larger product, they are less likeiy to be satisfied
`with similar products containing noninfringing alternative components. The more valuable the
`patented feature is to consumers, the larger the portion of the infringer’s sales that can be
`attributed to infringement. However, when consumers View a patented component as a minor
`feature that they would forgo at higher prices or substitute with noninfringing alternatives,
`infringement causes the patentee to lose fewer sales.27
`
`Under this economic analysis, the infringer’s sales are effectively “apportioned”
`according to the vaiue of the invention. This approach provides a more direct and accurate
`measure of a patentee’s harm from infringement when one component of a product is patented
`than does an attempt to measure that component’s relative contribution to a product or to appiy
`the entire market value rule.
`
`Recommendation. Courts should reject the entire market value rule as a basis for
`awarding a patentee lost profits damages based on all infringing sales, and instead require
`proofof the degree of consumer preference for the patented invention over alternatives.
`
`C.
`
`Dual Awards of Lost Profits and Reasonable Royaities
`
`When courts have awarded lost profits damages based on, a portion of the infringing sales,
`they also have sometimes awarded reasonable royalty damages on the remaining portion of
`infringing sales.28 Those cases refer to Section 284 of the Patent Act in reasoning that a patentee
`
`26See Juicy Whip, Inc. v. Orange Bang, Ind, 382 F.3d 1367, 1371~73 (Fed. Cir. 2004) (remanding for
`consideration of whether patentee was entitied to damages based on sales of unpatented syrup and
`because syrup and patented juice dispenser functioned together “to produce the visual appearance that
`was central to Juicy Whip’s ”405 patent”). If a patentee can prove that it would have made sales of an
`unpatented product along with a patented product but for the infringement, examining whether they
`function as a unit may be useful in determining whether lost sales of the unpatented product were
`“foreseeable” and compensable. See Blair & Cotter, supra note 3, at 89 (proposing this limited use of the
`functional unit test); Rire~Hite Corp, 56 F.3d at 1546 (requiring that lost profits be foreseeable to be
`compensable).
`
`27568 Blair & Cotter, supra note 3, at 17, 26-28; Leonard Comment at 8-9 (3/9/09).
`
`28State Indus, Inc, 883 F.2d at 1580; Rite-Hire Corp, 56 F.3d at 1554—55 (awarding lost profits damages
`on all but 502 sales and awarding reasonable royalties on those).
`
`156
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ868
`RX-0870.162
`
`

`

`is entitied to “no less than a reasonable royalty” on all of an infringer’s sales, even when it has
`received its profits lost due to infringement.29 In many instances, dual awards of test profits and
`reasonable royalty damages are inappropriate and courts should not award them.38
`
`When a patentee receives lost profits damages on lost sales amounting to only a portion
`of the infringer’s sales, the award recognizes that, but for infringement, the infringer would have
`sold an alternative to the patented invention. Putting the patentee in the position it would have
`been but for the infringement does not require compensating it for sales the infringer would have
`made of noninfringing alternatives. Awarding the patentee reasonable royalty damages on those
`sales in addition to lost profits overcompensates it compared to the market reward for the
`invention, because it ignores competition that the patented invention faced from noninfringing
`alternatives.31 Awarding lost profits damages based on a portion of the infringer’s sales can fully
`compensate the patentee for infringement, as required by Section 284.
`
`Recommendation. Courts should reject dual awards of lost profits and reasonable royalty
`damages when competition from alternatives would have prevented the patentee from
`making all the infringer’s sales in a world but for infringement.
`
`III.
`
`CONCLUSION
`
`The guiding principle in the calculation of lost profits damages is the construction of the
`hypothetical, market but for infringement.
`In that market, the patented invention may sometimes
`compete with noninfringing alternatives. Accurately calculating damages in the face of that
`competition requires an examination of consumer preferences for the patented invention over
`alternatives. Economic tools, including those frequently used in antitrust analysis. can support
`that calculation.
`
`The case law has evolved to recognize the importance of “the realities of the market.”32
`But further flexibility in the legal rules that apply to lost profits damages would allow a more
`economically grounded calculation, leading to more accurate awards and full compensation of
`
`29Rite—12579 Corp, 56 F.3d at 1554.
`
`30One situation in which dual awards might be appropriate is when markets for the patented
`product are separated by geography or type of use. A patentee may seek to earn royalties in one
`market (making reasonable royalty damages appropriate) but seil its invention exclusively in
`another (making lost profits appropriate). O‘Brien, supra note 11, at 21 n74.
`
`“See O’Brien, supra note ll, at 21-22; Comment of John W. Schlicher at 54 (5/11’09) (when law insists
`that patentcc recover damages on every infringing unit sold, the patentec is better off financially than it
`would have been absent infringement).
`
`3BSmithKline Diagnostics, Inc. v. Helena Lab. Corp, 926 F.2d l 161, l l66 (Fed. Cir. 1991) (considering
`whether “others would likely have captured sales made by the infiinger, despite a difference in the
`products”).
`
`157
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ869
`RX-0870.163
`
`

`

`patentees. Patentees that have proven entitlement to lost profits damages should not be denied
`that compensation and limited to reasonable royalties based on overly—rigorous requirements to
`show the precise amount of damages.
`
`To achieve accurate awards, calculation of lost profits damages must also take account of
`competition the patented product would have faced but for infringement. Courts should reject as
`not based on sound economics the entire market value rule and dual awards of lost profits and
`reasonable royalty damages in most situations. Additional focus on creating the world but for
`infringement, including a filll appreciation of the role of noninfringing alternatives in that world,
`will help compensate patentees through damages as the market would have done, avoiding the
`under and overcompensation that can harm innovation, competition and consumers.
`
`158
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ87O
`RX-0870.164
`
`

`

`THE HYPOTHE'I‘ICAL NEGO'I‘IA'I‘ION IN REASONABLE ROYALTY DAMAGES
`
`CHAPTER 6
`
`INTRODUCTION ................................................... 160
`
`II.
`
`RECENT CONTROVERSIES SURROUNDING REASONABLE
`
`ROYALTY DAMAGE AWARDS ....................................... 161
`
`A.
`
`B.
`
`C.
`
`Support for Damages Reform .................................... 161
`
`Opposition to Damages Reform . ................................. 163
`
`The Need to Review Damages Law ................................ 164
`
`III.
`
`OVERVIEW OF REASONABLE ROYALTY DAMAGES LA‘W ............ 165
`
`IV.
`
`CONCERNS WITH THE HYPOTHETICAL
`
`NEGOTIATION FRAMEWORK ...................................... 167
`
`A.
`
`B.
`
`The Counterfaetual Nature of the Hypothetical Negotiation ........... 170
`
`Deterrents t0 Infringement . ..................................... 173
`
`CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION . ........................... 175
`
`159
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ871
`RX-0870.165
`
`

`

`THE HYPOTHE'I‘ICAL NEGO'I‘IA'I‘ION IN REASONABLE ROYALTY DAMAGES
`
`CHAPTER 6
`
`I.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`Much of the controversy in the patent community concerning damage awards has focused
`on whether the law governing reasonable royalty damages appropriately compensates patentees.
`Different perspectives on this question have fueled a debate on the wisdom of legislative changes
`to reasonable royalty damages law as part of a broader patent law reform effort.1 Companies fall
`on opposite sides of this question depending on a number of factors, including whether they View
`themselves as more likely defendants or plaintiffs in patent litigation, whether they use patents
`primarily defensively or offensively, how likely it is that a patent in their industry might confer
`market power, and how many patents typically cover a single product.
`
`Different sides of the debate have at times looked to median damage awards as evidence
`of both the presence and the absence of a problem. But medians cannot answer the question of
`whether patent damages iaw appropriately compensates patentees. They supply no information
`about the accuracy of individual awards or the effect of very large awards that arguably motivate
`some litigation. That said, several factors suggest that a careful study of the economic
`underpinnings of reasonable royalty damages law would be beneficial. On the one hand, full
`compensation is important to incentivize invention and support licensing in a growing open
`technology paradigm.2 On the other hand, dramatic increases in litigation in the information
`technology (lT) industries and the rise in business models that use patents only to extract rents, if
`driven by awards that overcompensate patentees, could deter innovation and disrupt competition
`in technology markets.3
`
`As discussed in Chapter 4, damages law appropriately compensates patentees for
`infringement when it aligns damage awards with the economic value of the invention by
`replicating the market reward. When a patentee cannot or chooses not to prove lost profits or
`other direct harm, the market reward is the royalty to which a willing licensor and willing
`licensee would agree in a hypothetical negotiation. But courts sometimes reject, either implicitly
`or explicitly, a limitation based on the maximum amount a willing licensee would pay. In doing
`so, they often seem motivated by concerns about compensating patentees for unproven direct
`harm and deterring infringement. Those concerns are better addressed through other areas of
`remedies law, including lost profits damages, enhanced damages and injunctions. Allowing
`those concerns to distort the reasonable royalty damages calculation risks overcompensating
`patentees in litigation as compared to the market and creating problems such as higher prices,
`increased patent speculation, and decreased innovation.
`
`18. REP. N0. ”148, at 3 (2009).
`
`2596 Chapter 1.
`
`3See Chapter 2.
`
`160
`
`SKH_ITCOGOZ872
`RX-0870.166
`
`

`

`This Chapter and Chapter 7 seek to derive an economically grounded approach to
`calculating reasonable royalty damages and to compare that approach to the rules developed
`through case law. Ensuring that the iegal rules reflect an understanding of the economics
`underlying the market in which technology competes will heip align a patentee’s compensation
`with the economic value of the patented invention, and align patent law with competition policy.
`
`IL
`
`RECENT CONTROVERSIES SURROUNDING REASONABLE ROYALTY
`
`DAMAGE AWARDS
`
`A.
`
`Support for Damages Reform
`
`Those who compiain about the current state of damages law come mainly from the IT
`industries. They argue that patent value has become increasingly divorced from the economic
`value of the underlying technology in recent years because of excessive damages awards.4 From
`2002—2009, there were at least eleven damage awards over $100 million and one that was over $1
`billion, representing a marked increase in landmark damage awards compared to 20 years ago.5
`White some very large awards have been overturned,6 “outlier” cases still raise concerns because
`they inform and influence the licensing and settlement negotiations that resolve the vast majority
`
`4566, 8g, Yen at 47 ( 12/5/08) ( “Increasingly, activity in the marketplace is driven not by increased
`innovation but by efforts to exploit imbalances in a patent system that overvalues patents, particularly
`weak ones, and thereby actually suppresses marketplace innovation”); CCIA Comment at 6-7 (2/5/09);
`Doyle at 143 (5/5/09) (the current damages system “encourages what I wouid consider opportunistic
`litigation that has little relation to the value of a patent, its patent—worthiness, its validity, let alone
`whether or not it’s infringed”).
`
`5Paui Janicke, Patent Damages, Patent Verdicts from 1—1-05 to 1‘6—09, presented at FTC Hearing: The
`Evolving 1P Marketplace (Feb. 1 1, 2009), available at
`
`htt
`:X/ftc.crov/hc/worksho s/i marke lace/fab}1/docs/’anioke-medianverdits. df; Janickc at 9 (2/1 1/09)
`(explaining that these numbers are “only what the jury foreman announced” and do not reflect
`enhancements (cg, for wilifutness or interest) or subsequent judicial actions reducing or vacating the
`award). See (1230 Levko at 21 (2/11/09) (reporting that there had been “something like 22 cases” with
`awards over $100 miilion (in 20

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket