throbber
Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 1 of 13
`
`
`
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`
`NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
`
`Case No. 12-cv-05404-YGR
`
`
`
`ORDER GRANTING IN PART DENYING IN
`PART DEFENDANT’S MOTION FOR
`SUMMARY JUDGMENT
`Re: Dkt. Nos. 78, 126
`
`ZACK WARD, ET AL.,
`Plaintiffs,
`
`v.
`
`
`APPLE INC.,
`
`Defendant.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Plaintiffs Ward and Buchar bring this putative class action against defendant Apple Inc.
`
`alleging violations of Section 2 of the Sherman Act for a conspiracy to monopolize trade in the
`
`market for iPhone voice and data services. (Dkt. No. 1, “Comp.”)
`
`On December 15, 2015, the Court denied Apple’s motion to dismiss, but indicated that it
`
`would entertain a motion for summary judgment solely on the issue of the existence of a relevant
`
`market for antitrust purposes. (Dkt. No. 72.) Apple filed such motion on February 2, 2016. (Dkt.
`
`No. 78.) The Court heard oral arguments on the motion on March 29, 2016, and ordered the
`
`parties to conduct additional discovery, deferring ruling thereon. (Dkt. Nos. 97, 100.) With the
`
`benefit of additional discovery, the parties filed supplemental briefs in September and October of
`2016. (Dkt. Nos. 112, 118.)1
`
`
`1 On November 21, 2016, plaintiffs filed an administrative motion to supplement the
`summary judgment record and file a sur-reply. (Dkt. No. 126.) Having considered such motion,
`and for good cause appearing, the Court GRANTS plaintiffs’ administrative motion.
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 2 of 13
`
`
`
`Having considered the pleadings, the papers and exhibits submitted on the motion, and oral
`
`arguments held on January 31, 2017, and for the reasons set forth more fully below, the Court
`
`finds that plaintiffs have raised sufficient facts to show the existence of an antitrust market, albeit
`
`more narrow than plaintiffs contemplate. Accordingly, the Court GRANTS IN PART and DENIES IN
`PART Apple’s motion for summary judgment.2
`I.
`BACKGROUND
`
`Plaintiffs seek to represent a class of persons who purchased iPhones and paid for voice
`
`and data service from AT&T between October 19, 2008 and February 3, 2011 (the “Class
`
`Period”). Plaintiffs bring a single claim against Apple under Section 2 of the Sherman Act,
`
`alleging that Apple conspired with AT&T to monopolize an aftermarket for iPhone voice and data
`
`services. For purposes of the instant motion, Apple contends that no such illegal antitrust
`
`aftermarket exists under applicable laws and economic theories. The following undisputed facts
`
`are relevant to such argument and plaintiffs’ claims to the contrary:
`
`Apple launched its original cellular telephone, the iPhone 2G, on June 29, 2007. (Dkt. No.
`
`83-8, Fenger Decl. ¶ 8.) Prior to such launch, Apple and AT&T entered into an agreement by
`
`which AT&T would be the exclusive provider of cellular voice and data service for the iPhone in
`the United States (the “Agreement”). (Id. at ¶ 9.)3 By the terms of the Agreement, the exclusivity
`period was to end five years after the effective date of the Agreement, i.e. August 10, 2011. (Dkt.
`
`No. 83-9 at 2, 5.) The Agreement also allowed either party to terminate the Agreement for
`
`convenience and upon notice, prior to the second anniversary of the iPhone’s commercial launch.
`
`(Id. at 19.) Thus, given that the iPhone’s commercial launch was June 29, 2007 (Fenger Decl. ¶
`
`8), AT&T was only guaranteed to be the exclusive provider for the iPhone until June 29, 2009.
`
`
`2 In connection with the parties’ filings on this motion, they submitted administrative
`motions to file parts of their briefs and certain exhibits under seal. (Dkt. Nos. 83, 90, 111, 117,
`and 125.) The Court addresses each of those motions by separate order.
`3 During the periods relevant to the instant action, similar exclusivity provisions between
`cellular phone manufacturers and service and data providers were common in the industry, at least
`for limited periods of time. (See Fenger Decl. ¶¶ 2–3; Dkt. No. 111-8, Wilkie Decl. ¶ 27.)
`
`2
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 3 of 13
`
`
`
`In June 2008, around the time the second generation of iPhones was being released (the
`
`iPhone 3G), Apple and AT&T modified the Agreement to include a different and specific
`
`termination date, namely December 31, 2010. The amendment to the Agreement also provided for
`
`a significant change to the manner in which Apple earned revenues from the sales of the iPhone.
`
`Under the original Agreement, Apple shared in the revenues earned by AT&T from its sales of
`
`voice and data service for iPhones. (Dkt. No. 83-9 at 6–7.) The amendment eliminated revenue
`
`sharing and replaced it with a subsidy model, through which AT&T agreed to subsidize the cost of
`the iPhone if the buyer agreed to enter into a two-year service contract. (Dkt. No. 83-10 at 3–5.)4
`Prior to, and during the Class Period, Apple and AT&T advertised both that AT&T would
`
`be the exclusive provider of voice and data service for the iPhone (at least in the United States)
`
`and that consumers were required to purchase a two-year contract with AT&T to activate the
`
`iPhone. (Dkt. No. 80-1 at 2.) Such information also appeared in the following: (i) the box in
`
`which the iPhone was sold (Dkt. No. 80-2 at 2); (ii) certain websites related to Apple and AT&T
`
`(Dkt. No. 120-4); and (iii) a pop-up screen during the iPhone activation process (Dkt. No. 79-1 at
`
`3). In light of these disclosures and the subsidy model in place during the Class Period, the iPhone
`was essentially sold bundled together with a two-year service plan through AT&T.5 Relevant
`here, the two-year service plan contracts entered into between consumers and AT&T allowed
`
`consumers to terminate their plans with AT&T upon payment of a $175 termination fee. (Dkt.
`
`No. 82-3 at 11.) Additionally, in such a case, the contract allowed AT&T to recover “any
`
`handsets and accessories purchased with” the service plan. (Id.)
`
`
`4 During the Class Period, the parties agree that such a subsidy model was the industry
`standard by which “virtually all cellular phones” have been sold in the United States. (Dkt. No.
`111-6 at 7, Issue 1, Fact 17.)
`5 Plaintiffs submitted evidence suggesting that, at least in some circumstances, gaps
`existed between when consumers purchased an iPhone and when they activated or purchased
`AT&T service for the same. (See, e.g., Dkt. No. 111-2 at 2 (indicating that the average delay
`between purchase and activation for iPhones from June through September 2007 was two days).)
`However, for the reasons stated herein, the Court finds such gaps irrelevant for the purposes of
`determining whether a relevant antitrust market exists for iPhone voice and data services.
`
`3
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 4 of 13
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Notwithstanding the foregoing, plaintiffs have also produced evidence suggesting that the
`
`unlock codes for the iPhones, necessary to enable the iPhone’s use with other carriers, were not
`
`released by AT&T until April 2012. (Dkt. No. 113-9 at 2.) Notably, until the exclusivity
`
`agreement formally ended in December 2010, iPhones were produced to function only on the
`
`Global System for Mobile communication network (“GSM”). (Fenger Decl. ¶ 7.) At the time,
`
`two major United States networks existed for cellular service, namely the GSM network and the
`
`Code Division Multiple Access network (“CDMA”). (See Dkt. No. 111-8, Wilkie Decl. at ¶¶ 10–
`
`11.) During the Class Period, generally, phones built to operate on the GSM network were limited
`
`to AT&T or T-Mobile as providers while those built to operate on the CDMA network were
`
`limited to using either Sprint or Verizon. (Id.) Thus, some evidence suggests that consumers who
`
`purchased a GSM-compatible iPhone prior to December 31, 2010 still had to remain on the AT&T
`network until April 2012, or else purchase a new phone.6 Additionally, an open factual question
`remains as to whether iPhone purchasers were aware that AT&T and Apple would refuse to
`unlock their phones for purposes of international travel.7
`II.
`LEGAL FRAMEWORK FOR SUMMARY JUDGMENT
`
`Summary judgment is appropriate when no genuine dispute as to any material fact exists
`
`and the moving party is entitled to judgment as a matter of law. Fed. R. Civ. P. 56(a). A party
`
`seeking summary judgment bears the initial burden of informing the court of the basis for its
`
`motion, and of identifying those portions of the pleadings, depositions, discovery responses, and
`
`
`6 A dispute of fact exists as to whether the GSM-compatible iPhones could fully operate
`on the T-Mobile network during the Class Period. However, such dispute is not material to the
`Court’s ruling on Apple’s motion, and thus, the Court need not address the same at this time. (See
`Dkt. No. 111-6 at 3, Issue 1, Fact 6.)
`7 In this regard, Dr. Wilkie opined thus: “Cellular carriers, including ATTM, customarily
`unlock a GSM phone when a customer travels overseas. This allows customers to replace the SIM
`card with a card from a local cellular carrier and thus avoid international roaming fees. However,
`ATTM has refused to unlock iPhones. Consumers who paid anticompetitive foreign roaming
`charges to ATTM suffered a common impact. I understand that ATTM has developed a
`methodology that it has used to compensate some iPhone customers who have paid such foreign
`roaming charges. I anticipate that, following further discovery, I will be able to evaluate ATTM’s
`methodology and determine how many iPhone customers have been partially or fully compensated
`by ATTM so that I can calculate the economic damages resulting from ATTM’s anticompetitive
`roaming charges.” (Dkt. No. 111-8, Wilkie Decl. ¶ 70.)
`
`4
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 5 of 13
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`affidavits that demonstrate the absence of a genuine issue of material fact. Celotex Corp. v.
`
`Catrett, 477 U.S. 317, 323 (1986). Material facts are those that might affect the outcome of the
`
`case. Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 477 U.S. 242, 248 (1986). The “mere existence of some
`
`alleged factual dispute between the parties will not defeat an otherwise properly supported motion
`
`for summary judgment; the requirement is that there be no genuine issue of material fact.” Id. at
`
`247–48 (dispute as to a material fact is “genuine” if sufficient evidence exists for a reasonable jury
`
`to return a verdict for the non-moving party) (emphases in original).
`
`Where the moving party will have the burden of proof at trial, it must affirmatively
`
`demonstrate that no reasonable trier of fact could find other than for the moving party. Soremekun
`
`v. Thrifty Payless, Inc., 509 F.3d 978, 984 (9th Cir. 2007). On an issue where the opposing party
`
`will bear the burden of proof at trial, the moving party can prevail merely by pointing out to the
`
`district court that the opposing party lacks evidence to support its case. Id. If the moving party
`
`meets its initial burden, the opposing party must then set out “specific facts” showing a genuine
`
`issue for trial in order to defeat the motion. Id. (quoting Anderson, 477 U.S. at 250). The
`
`opposing party’s evidence must be more than “merely colorable” and must be “significantly
`
`probative.” Anderson, 477 U.S. at 249–50. Further, that party may not rest upon mere allegations
`
`or denials of the adverse party’s evidence, but instead must produce admissible evidence that
`
`shows a genuine issue of material fact exists for trial. Nissan Fire & Marine Ins. Co., Ltd. v. Fritz
`
`Cos., Inc., 210 F.3d 1099, 1102–03 (9th Cir. 2000); Nelson v. Pima Cmty. College Dist., 83 F.3d
`
`1075, 1081–82 (9th Cir. 1996) (“mere allegation and speculation do not create a factual dispute”);
`
`Arpin v. Santa Clara Valley Transp. Agency, 261 F.3d 912, 922 (9th Cir. 2001) (“conclusory
`
`allegations unsupported by factual data are insufficient to defeat [defendants’] summary judgment
`
`motion”).
`
`When deciding a summary judgment motion, a court must view the evidence in the light
`
`most favorable to the non-moving party and draw all justifiable inferences in its favor. Anderson,
`
`477 U.S. at 255; Hunt v. City of Los Angeles, 638 F.3d 703, 709 (9th Cir. 2011). However, in
`
`determining whether to grant or deny summary judgment, a court need not “scour the record in
`
`search of a genuine issue of triable fact.” Keenan v. Allan, 91 F.3d 1275, 1279 (9th Cir. 1996)
`5
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 6 of 13
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`(internal quotations omitted). Rather, a court is entitled to “rely on the nonmoving party to
`
`identify with reasonable particularity the evidence that precludes summary judgment.” See id.;
`
`Carmen v. San Francisco Unified Sch. Dist., 237 F.3d 1026, 1031 (9th Cir. 2001) (“The district
`
`court need not examine the entire file for evidence establishing a genuine issue of fact, where the
`
`evidence is not set forth in the opposing papers with adequate references so that it could
`
`conveniently be found.”). Ultimately, “[w]here the record taken as a whole could not lead a
`
`rational trier of fact to find for the nonmoving-party, there is no genuine issue for trial.”
`
`Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co., Ltd. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 587 (1986) (citation
`
`omitted).
`III.
`ANTITRUST AFTERMARKETS UNDER KODAK AND NEWCAL
`
`To prove a conspiracy to monopolize in violation of Section 2, plaintiffs must prove four
`
`elements: “(1) the existence of a combination or conspiracy to monopolize; (2) an overt act in
`
`furtherance of the conspiracy; (3) the specific intent to monopolize; and (4) causal antitrust
`
`injury.” Paladin Assocs., Inc. v. Montana Power Co., 328 F.3d 1145, 1158 (9th Cir. 2003).
`
`Additionally, plaintiffs must prove both that a “relevant market exists and that the defendant has
`
`power within that market.” Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1044 (9th Cir.
`
`2008). Here, plaintiffs assert that the “relevant market” is the aftermarket for iPhone voice and
`
`data services, arguing that Apple’s undisclosed exclusivity arrangement with AT&T illegally
`
`created a monopoly in the same. (Dkt. No. 90-4 at 7.)
`
`Plaintiffs’ claims emanate from the Supreme Court’s watershed decision in Eastman
`
`Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992), which created a new avenue
`
`for plaintiffs to allege a relevant antitrust market. In Kodak, the Supreme Court addressed the
`
`juxtaposition of a defendant’s market power in the primary equipment market, or lack thereof,
`
`with the possibility of market power in derivative aftermarkets. Id. at 455. The Supreme Court
`
`held that competition in the primary equipment market does not necessarily preclude antitrust
`
`liability in certain circumstances for derivative aftermarkets. Id. at 471.
`
`The markets addressed in Kodak involved the following: (i) a primary market for
`
`photocopiers and micrographic equipment and (ii) a derivative aftermarket for service and
`6
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 7 of 13
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`replacement parts for such equipment. Id. With respect to the latter, beginning in the early 1980s,
`
`independent service organizations (“ISOs”) unrelated to the Eastman Kodak Company began
`
`repairing and servicing Kodak equipment. Id. at 457. However, in the late 1980s, Kodak
`
`implemented a new policy in which it would only sell replacement parts for its machines to
`
`“buyers of Kodak equipment who use Kodak service or repair their own machines,” effectively
`
`eliminating ISO competition in the service aftermarket. Id. at 458. The ISOs filed suit against
`
`Kodak claiming that it had “unlawfully monopolized and attempted to monopolize the sale of
`
`service for Kodak machines.” Id.
`
`The district court granted summary judgment in favor of Kodak and the Ninth Circuit
`
`reversed holding that Kodak had “sufficient economic power in the tying product market [parts] to
`
`restrain competition appreciably in the tied product market [service].” Id. at 460. The Ninth
`
`Circuit further held that it was enough that the ISOs had “presented evidence of actual events from
`
`which a reasonable trier of fact could conclude that . . . competition in the [equipment] market
`
`does not, in reality, curb Kodak’s power in the parts market.” Id. On appeal, the Supreme Court
`
`acknowledged that the tying arrangement alleged in the complaint could be a violation of the
`
`antitrust laws if the “seller has ‘appreciable economic power’ in the tying product market and if
`
`the arrangement affects a substantial volume of commerce in the tied market.” Id. at 462. Kodak
`
`did not dispute that its arrangement affected a substantial volume of interstate commerce but
`
`argued that (i) its activities were not a tying arrangement and (ii) in any event, it did not exercise
`
`appreciable economic power in the tying market. Id.
`
`The second of these arguments is most relevant to the instant motion. Kodak contended
`
`that it could not exercise the necessary market power for a Sherman Act violation because
`
`competition existed in the equipment market. Id. at 465. Specifically, Kodak argued that any
`
`exercise of market power in the market for parts and service “at least would be offset by a
`
`corresponding loss in profits from lower equipment sales as consumers began purchasing
`
`equipment with more attractive service costs.” Id. at 466. The Supreme Court held that, as a
`
`matter of law, the “fact that the equipment market imposes a restraint on prices in the aftermarket
`
`by no means disproves the existence of power in those markets.” Id. at 471 (holding that there “is
`7
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 8 of 13
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`no immutable physical law—no ‘basic economic reality’—insisting that competition in the
`
`equipment market cannot coexist with market power in the aftermarkets”).
`
`The Supreme Court thus proceeded to the narrower question of whether, under the
`
`circumstances in Kodak, the assertion of power in the aftermarket was unreasonable. Id. Kodak’s
`
`central theory was that higher service prices would lead to a drop in equipment sales. Id. at 472.
`
`However, the evidence in the record revealed otherwise. The Supreme Court found persuasive the
`
`ISOs’ explanation that the existence of “significant information and switching costs” could “create
`
`a less responsive connection between service and parts prices and equipment sales,” thus allowing
`
`Kodak to exercise market power in the former even where competition existed in the latter. Id. at
`
`473 (explaining that for the “service-market price to affect equipment demand, consumers must
`
`inform themselves of the total cost of the ‘package’—equipment, service, and parts—at the time of
`
`purchase; that is, consumers must engage in accurate lifecycle pricing”).
`
`With regard to information costs, the Supreme Court explained: “Given the potentially
`
`high cost of information and the possibility that a seller may be able to price discriminate between
`
`knowledgeable and unsophisticated consumers, it makes little sense to assume, in the absence of
`
`any evidentiary support, that equipment-purchasing decisions are based on an accurate assessment
`
`of the total cost of equipment, service, and parts over the lifetime of the machine.” Id. at 475–76.
`
`With regard to switching costs, the Supreme Court stated that a “seller profitably could maintain
`
`supracompetitive prices in the aftermarket if the switching costs were high relative to the increase
`
`in service prices, and the number of locked-in customers were high relative to the number of new
`
`purchasers.” Id. at 476. On such bases, the Supreme Court held that there was a question of fact
`
`“whether information costs and switching costs foil the simple assumption that the equipment and
`
`service markets act as pure complements to one another.” Id. at 477.
`
`The Supreme Court’s decision in Kodak thus created the framework within which courts
`
`have addressed antitrust liability in the context of derivative aftermarkets. The Ninth Circuit
`
`grappled with the same in analyzing the existence of a relevant antitrust aftermarket in Newcal.
`
`There, parties leased name-brand copier equipment to commercial customers and also provided
`
`service “contracts for the maintenance of that equipment during the term of the lease.” Id. at 1043.
`8
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 9 of 13
`
`
`
`The plaintiff in Newcal alleged that the defendant exercised illegal market power over the
`
`aftermarket for lease-end service contracts by amending “customers’ lease agreements and service
`
`contracts without disclosing that the amendments would lengthen the term of the original
`
`contract.” Id.
`
`The district court dismissed the action, finding that the plaintiff had failed to allege a
`
`relevant antitrust market, and the Ninth Circuit reversed. Id. at 1044. In so reversing, the Ninth
`
`Circuit acknowledged three antitrust principles: First, “the law permits an antitrust claimant to
`
`restrict the relevant market to a single brand of the product at issue.” Id. at 1048. Second,
`
`antitrust claims cannot rest on “market power that arises solely from contractual rights that
`consumers knowingly and voluntarily gave to the defendant.” Id. (emphasis in original).8 Third,
`given the law allows an “inquiry into whether a consumer’s selection of a particular brand in the
`
`competitive market is the functional equivalent of a contractual commitment,” the analysis should
`
`center on whether such consumers entered into certain transactions “knowing that they were
`
`agreeing to such a commitment.” Id.at 1049.
`
`Against this legal framework, both parties cite approvingly to an article published not long
`
`after the Supreme Court’s decision in Kodak, which lays out four different economic
`
`circumstances in which an antitrust market could manifest. See Carl Shapiro, Aftermarkets and
`
`Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak, 63 Antitrust L.J. 483 (Winter 1995). Of particular
`relevance to the situation at bar is Shapiro’s “surprise” theory of antitrust aftermarkets.9 “The
`surprise theory starts from the assumption that buyers in the aftermarket are vulnerable, and asks
`
`whether the equipment manufacturer will find it profitable to unexpectedly change its policies so
`
`as to exploit them.” Id. at 488. Shapiro explains that under this theory, injury would occur if
`
`
`8 The Ninth Circuit in Newcal acknowledges that where “alleged market power flows from
`contractual exclusivity,” an antitrust aftermarket is not created. Id. at 1050 (citing Queen City
`Pizza, Inc. v. Domino’s Pizza, Inc., 124 F.3d 430 (3d Cir. 1997) and Forsyth v. Humana, Inc., 114
`F.3d 1467 (9th Cir. 1997)). Apple, however, concedes that it does not fall under Newcal’s safe
`harbor for contractually created rights. Thus, the Court does not address such issues further.
`9 The parties have not focused on the other three theories: (i) costly information; (ii)
`limited manufacturer commitment; and (iii) price discrimination.
`
`9
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 10 of 13
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`“buyers had anticipated or relied on competitive aftermarkets, but some change in the
`
`manufacturer’s policies blocked that competition.” Id.
`
`Thus, with this background in mind, the Court turns to an analysis of whether the particular
`
`circumstances surrounding sales of the iPhone and purchasing service from AT&T during the
`
`proposed Class Period gave rise to an antitrust aftermarket, and if so, to what extent.
`IV.
`
`DISCUSSION
`
`To assert a relevant antitrust market in the secondary market, plaintiffs first argue the
`
`existence of a separate and distinct secondary market. Said differently, plaintiffs claim that the
`
`primary purchase of the iPhone created a locked-in base of consumers who were then forced to
`purchase iPhone voice and data services from AT&T, i.e. the secondary market.10 To support this
`argument, plaintiffs claim, as they must, that the purchase of the iPhone and the service contracts
`
`were temporally distinct transactions.
`
`The Court disagrees. To the extent any temporal disconnect existed between the purchase
`of the iPhone and the activation of AT&T services, the Court finds the period insignificant.11
`Although some buyers may not have activated their iPhone and AT&T service for several days
`
`after purchasing the iPhone, the purchase of the initial two-year contract was essentially linked to
`
`the purchase of the iPhone. Apple produced several pieces of evidence indicating that a minimum
`
`“new two-year wireless service plan with AT&T” was “required to activate all iPhone features,
`
`including iPod features.” (Dkt. No. 80-2 at 2; see also Dkt. No. 79-1 at 3.) Plaintiffs themselves
`
`were aware when they purchased their iPhones that they also had to enter into a service agreement
`
`with AT&T. (Dkt. No. 126-2, Ward Dep. Tr. 68:19–69:11; Dkt. No. 126-3, Buchar Dep. Tr.
`
`
`10 Plaintiffs further argue that an aftermarket was also created by Apple and AT&T’s
`refusal to unlock the iPhone during the two-year contract after users paid a termination fee.
`However, given the evidence of disclosures and information available to the consumers
`surrounding the sale of the iPhone, and the subsidy model in effect during the Class Period, the
`Court is not persuaded. Consumers explicitly locked themselves into a two-year agreement with
`AT&T, knowing that the same would be required to utilize the cellular capabilities of the iPhone.
`Additionally, the two-year service contract with AT&T included a provision that consumers may
`have to return their handsets should they terminate the plan prematurely.
`11 Plaintiffs note that discovery documents revealed that the average delay between
`purchase of the iPhone and activation of AT&T services was 1.5 days.
`
`10
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 11 of 13
`
`
`
`16:15–17:12.) Thus, at least with respect to the initial two-year agreement with AT&T, no
`
`evidence has been proffered that a “surprise” existed leading to a market hostage to defendant.
`
`Information regarding the need to purchase a two-year AT&T service plan was widely known, and
`
`plaintiffs have put forward no evidence to the contrary. See, e.g., Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1049
`
`(finding that the primary product market included the equipment lease and initial service contract
`
`and that the secondary product market consisted of the replacement equipment and lease-end
`
`service contracts).
`
`Plaintiffs next argue that where, as in Newcal, the sales are tied, a market existed because
`
`of the “surprise” caused by the existence of a secret, five-year exclusivity agreement between
`
`Apple and AT&T. Plaintiffs’ first expert, Dr. Simon Wilke, opined as part of the initial opposition
`
`to Apple’s motion for summary judgment that this surprise effectively locked-in “iPhone
`
`customers for a substantial period beyond the term specified in their agreements with [AT&T].”
`
`(Dkt. No. 111-10 at 4, ¶¶ 2, 8 (finding that “iPhone customers did not agree at the time they signed
`
`the service contract with [AT&T] to make [AT&T] their exclusive iPhone carrier for a period of
`
`time extending beyond the two-year term of that contract”); see also Dkt. No. 111-8 at 21, ¶ 33
`
`(describing that the market power could be exercised by “withholding information regarding the
`
`five-year term of the Apple/[AT&T] agreement, thereby causing iPhone customers who entered
`
`into two-year agreements to either (1) stop using their iPhones for telecommunications purposes,
`
`or (2) continue to use [AT&T] after their two-year agreement expired, effectively locking in
`
`iPhone customers for a substantially longer period”).) Discovery has undermined plaintiffs’
`
`theory. The evidence now shows that the “five-year exclusivity deal” between Apple and AT&T
`
`never materialized. Summary judgment on this theory is therefore appropriate.
`
`Given the lack of evidence, plaintiffs’ replacement expert, Dr. Frederick Warren-Boulton,
`
`adds nothing to plaintiffs’ arguments based on the five-year exclusivity theory. However, he does
`
`offer an additional theory that a market existed after the expiration of the two-year contract. (See
`
`11
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 4:12-cv-05404-YGR Document 146 Filed 03/22/17 Page 12 of 13
`
`
`
`Dkt. No. 114-1 at 12, ¶ 11.)12 With respect to this claim, plaintiffs have submitted evidence
`showing that defendant may have manipulated a market for service plans where defendant failed
`
`or refused to unlock the phones after the expiration of the two-year commitment for either
`domestic or international use. (See Dkt. No. 113-9 at 2.)13
`The Court agrees as to this more narrow theory. Even though Apple was no longer bound
`
`to create iPhones that could only function on the GSM network after 2010, those who purchased
`
`iPhones prior to the end of exclusivity still had to remain on the GSM network. These consumers
`
`could have expected to switch to another GSM provider, like T-Mobile, at the end of the two-year
`
`contract with AT&T. However, as plaintiffs’ evidence suggests, AT&T did not begin providing
`
`unlock codes for such phones until April 2012. Consequently, these consumers would have been
`
`locked into renewing AT&T service, or else lose the cellular capabilities of their iPhones. In this
`
`context, the Court DENIES summary judgment with regard to any such claims.
`
`Finally, the Court addresses Apple’s argument that summary judgment should be granted
`
`generally and as a matter of law based solely on the failure to include all economic substitutes in
`
`the market definition. The Court disagrees. Newcal held the law “permits an antitrust claimant to
`
`restrict the relevant market to a single brand of the product at issue.” Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1048.
`
`In evaluating the market at issue, courts look to various factors. No one factor is dispositive. See
`
`Red Lion Medical Safety, Inc. v. Ohmeda, I

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket